Please wait as we load hundreds of rigorously documented facts for you.



YOUR SOURCE FOR RELIABLE RESEARCH

What You’ll Find

For example:


Citation Generator
X
APA
MLA
Chicago (for footnotes)
Chicago (for bibliographies)

Purpose and History of Money

* Money is any standardized financial medium for making payments and settling debts.[1]

* Money serves as a:

  • medium of exchange that is used to buy goods and services.
  • unit of account to determine prices.
  • store of value that allows people to buy goods and services in the future.[2]

Antiquity

* Before humans invented money, they traded with barter—the direct exchange of goods and services.[3] [4]

* People used common goods such as cattle, tea, and raw metals for barter.[5] Other barter items included tools, jewelry, and weapons.[6]

* Barter was inefficient because it required the “double coincidence of wants”—the condition of “two people each having a good that the other wants at the right time and place to make an exchange.”[7]

* As far back as the 13th century BC, societies in Asia, Africa, and Europe began using seashells known as cowries for money.[8]

Cowries

Cowrie Shells

Photo credit: Fotolia/jamocki

* At the end of the Stone Age, China developed a currency system using metals. Copper and bronze were cast to depict cowrie shells, tools, and knives.[9]

* The “stater” coin of the Lydian Empire (modern Turkey) is the earliest known currency issued by a government. It was first minted around the second half of the seventh century BC. The value of the coin was based on a strict weight standard.[10] [11]

* War and trade spread coins from Lydia across the Persian Empire, Greece, Sicily, Macedonia, and India.[12]

* The gold solidus, first minted by the Roman Emperor Constantine in the early fourth century AD, is one of history’s most famous coins. It was produced at a constant weight for 700 years.[13]


Middle Ages

* England standardized the silver penny around 765 AD, and it was widely used in Northern Europe.[14]

* English money was known as “sterling,” and 240 silver pennies made up one “pound sterling.” The silver used for the coins had to meet strict purity standards. From 1078 until 1914, the term “pound sterling” meant high-quality and stability.[15]

* In mainland Europe, gold coins—such as florins from Florence and Ghent, and ducats from Venice—were the primary coins used in international trade.[16]

* For large expenses, Chinese merchants developed paper money around the tenth century AD. This was several centuries before Europe used paper currency.[17]


Modern Age

* During the 1500s, silver mined at St. Joachimsthal in Bohemia was used to mint the thaler, which circulated in Germany for more than 300 years.[18] The Spanish version of the thaler—the peso—was used in the Americas during the colonial era, and became the basis for the American dollar.[19] [20]

* In 1717, the United Kingdom’s Master of the Mint, Sir Isaac Newton, defined the pound sterling’s value in terms of gold rather than silver for the first time.[21]

* Starting with the Coinage Act of 1792, the United States used a bimetallic currency standard. This means the dollar was defined by its value in both silver and gold.[22]

* In the early 19th century, Britain officially adopted the gold standard.[23] During the 1870s, Germany, Holland, Austro-Hungary, Russia, Scandinavia, and France also switched to the gold standard.[24]

* The United States officially adopted the gold standard with the Gold Standard Act of 1900.[25]

* In 1913, in response to a series of banking crises, the U.S. Congress established the Federal Reserve.[26]

* During World War I, many countries suspended the gold standard and began printing money to finance the war effort, which led to high inflation.[27] By 1919, the United States was the only world power that still followed the gold standard.[28]

* After World War I, Britain and other European countries briefly returned to the gold standard.[29]

* Britain left the gold standard in 1931 amidst the Great Depression, and the value of British money dropped significantly.[30] [31] Other nations that relied heavily on Britain for trade then dropped the gold standard to prevent Britain’s weak currency from pricing their “goods out of the large market which Britain provided.”[32]

* In 1934, the United States reduced the dollar’s value by raising the price of gold from $20.67 to $35 per ounce. The federal government also stopped allowing Americans to exchange their dollars for gold, and it confiscated privately-held gold.[33] [34]

* In 1944, delegates from 44 nations met in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to establish a new international monetary system. These countries agreed to value their currencies according to the U.S. dollar for international trade. In turn, the U.S. dollar would keep a fixed value of $35 per ounce of gold.[35]

* The Bretton Woods delegates also created the International Monetary Fund and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (now called World Bank Group) to help run the new system.[36]

* In 1971, Republican President Richard Nixon stopped allowing the exchange of dollars into gold, thus ending the Bretton Woods system. Most of the world’s currencies therefore had no link to a metal standard. Per the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond:

Except during periods of global crisis, this was the first time in history that most of the monies of the industrialized world were on an irredeemable paper money standard.[37]

* From 1965 to 1982, inflation in the United States increased multiplicatively during an era known as the Great Inflation. The annual inflation rate ranged from just over 1% in 1964 to over 14% in 1980.[38] [39] [40]

* In the early 1980s, the Federal Reserve enacted policies to raise private-sector interest rates. These high interest rates reduced inflation amid the recession of 1981–82.[41] [42] [43]

* The period from the mid-1980s to 2007 is known as the Great Moderation, when inflation stabilized and the economy expanded.[44] Part of this expansion took place in housing-related industries such as construction and mortgage borrowing.[45]

* From 1998 to 2006, home prices rose at unprecedented rates. In 2007, prices began dropping.[46] As housing prices fell, financial institutions lost money because of borrowers defaulting on mortgages. These losses had “large spillover effects” on other parts of the economy. This led to the Great Recession that began in December 2007 and ended in 2009.[47] [48] [49]

* In response to the Great Recession, the Federal Reserve:

  • reduced the interest rate that banks use to borrow from one another for short-term loans from 5.25% to about 0%.[50] [51]
  • implemented an unconventional policy called quantitative easing.[52] This included creating new money to purchase:[53] [54]
    • $175 billion of debt belonging to government-sponsored mortgage-related agencies, such as Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks, in 2008–2010.[55] [56]
    • $1.25 trillion of mortgage-related investments—“toxic assets”—from Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, the Federal Home Loan Banks, and Ginnie Mae in 2009–2010.[57] [58] [59]
    • “very large amounts” of government debt beginning in 2009, which by January 2016 totaled over $2 trillion.[60]

* Recovery from the Great Recession was a period of slow growth.[61] From 2010 to 2016, real (inflation-adjusted) GDP growth averaged 2.2% annually. From 1946 to 2007, the average annual growth rate was 3.2%.[62]


Virtual Currencies and Cryptocurrencies

* A digital currency is a computerized representation of money. This includes traditional currencies that are transferred electronically and currencies that exist mainly in digital form.[63]

* A virtual currency is stored and/or traded digitally but is not legally recognized by a government. Some, such as the gold that players earn in the online game World of Warcraft, cannot be converted into other currencies. Others, such as the now-defunct e-Gold, can be exchanged into traditional currencies. Most virtual currencies are centralized, meaning they have an administrator that controls its supply and makes rules for its use. [64] [65]

* Cryptocurrencies are a subset of virtual currencies that do not have central administrators. They use automated computer networks, instead of banks, to verify and process payments. Cryptocurrencies can be exchanged for traditional currencies.[66] [67] [68] [69] [70]

* In 2009, an anonymous computer programmer invented Bitcoin—the first cryptocurrency.[71] [72]

* Another cryptocurrency, XRP, was introduced by the company Ripple in 2012. It is primarily used as a currency to facilitate cross-border payments between banks.[73] [74]

* The computer network groups together a set of transactions, called a block. Computers across the network confirm the transactions contained in the block. Each block then becomes part of a shared public record—a block chain.[75] [76] [77]

* Because payment verifications are automated and recorded across an entire network, cryptocurrency trade is neutral and transparent.[78] [79] [80] [81]

* Cryptocurrency payments can be made at any time, since they do not rely on a third party bank for confirmation. They are also settled more quickly than traditional transactions. The process for a merchant to receive payment from a credit card transaction takes 24 to 72 hours. An average Bitcoin transaction takes 10 minutes, and an average XRP transaction takes four seconds.[82] [83] [84]

* Transactions using cryptocurrencies may have lower fees than traditional credit card transactions because they do not involve multiple intermediaries. In some cases, they have no transaction fee, whereas businesses typically pay 2% to 3% in fees to credit card companies.[85] [86] [87]

* The blockchain technology used in cryptocurrency transactions makes it nearly impossible to reverse payments. Businesses may see this as a benefit, because they are not at risk for chargebacks by customers.[88] [89]

* The value of a virtual currency is not tied to a commodity such as gold and is not declared to be legal tender by a government. Instead, it has value because people agree to use and accept it as payment.[90] [91] [92]

* The value of a cryptocurrency can change quickly.[93] [94] [95] According to Lael Brainard, a member of the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors:[96]

Such extreme fluctuations limit an asset’s ability to fulfill two of the classic functions of money: to act as a stable store of value that people can hold and use predictably in the future, and to serve as a meaningful unit of account that can be used to assign a comparable value of goods and services.[97]

Inflation and Deflation

Definitions & Causes

* Inflation is a general rise in prices for goods and services due to a decline in a currency’s value, or purchasing power.[98] [99] [100]

* Hyperinflation is extremely high inflation—over 50% per month.[101]

* When a government increases the supply of money faster than the economy demands it, the purchasing power of the currency shrinks and prices increase.[102] [103]

* Market forces can also have inflationary effects:

  • “Cost-push” inflation occurs when a supply shortage or unexpected cost increase pushes up general prices. For example, a spike in gas prices increases the cost of transportation, which causes higher prices in a wide range of products.
  • “Demand-pull” inflation occurs when sudden increased demand for products exceeds supply and pulls up general prices. An extended stock market rally is one example.[104]

* Deflation is the opposite of inflation—general prices fall as the purchasing power of money increases.[105]

* There are four major causes of deflation:

  1. The government produces money slower than the economy demands it.[106] [107]
  2. The government reduces the money supply excessively.[108]
  3. Poor economic conditions such as slow growth or high unemployment cause a drop in overall spending and an increased demand for cash.[109] [110]
  4. Sudden increased productivity or reduced production costs—such as from technological advancements—increase overall product supply faster than the market demands it.[111] [112]

Measures

* Inflation is measured by looking at prices for a wide range of goods and services over time.[113]

* The Federal Reserve mainly uses the Personal Consumption Expenditures (PCE) index, calculated by the Department of Commerce, to guide policy.[114]

* The Bureau of Labor Statistics calculates the Consumer Price Index (CPI), which is the most widely used measure of inflation. It affects the income of about 80 million people because it is used to adjust Social Security, food stamp, military retirement, and federal civil service retirement benefits. It is also used to determine school lunch prices and adjust the federal income tax code.[115]

* Although PCE and CPI follow the same general trends, there are differences between them:

  • In both indexes, the prices of some goods are assigned more weight than others. The weight assigned to each good in CPI is based on what consumers are buying, while the weights in PCE are based on what businesses are selling.[116] [117]
  • PCE includes costs that are not paid directly out-of-pocket—such as medical expenses covered by employer-provided insurance—while CPI does not.[118] [119]
  • A different economic formula is used to calculate each index.[120] [121]

* From 1929 to 2017, the annual inflation rate as measured by CPI ranged from –9.9% to 14.4%, with a median of 2.8% and an average of 3.1%. During the same time period, the annual inflation rate as measured by PCE ranged from –11.8% to 12.5%, with a median of 2.5% and an average of 2.8%:

CPI and PCE Annual Inflation Rates

[122]

* From 1929 to 2017, the cumulative inflation rate was 1,333% as measured by CPI and 1,036% as measured by PCE:

CPI and PCE Cumulative Inflation Rates Since 1929

[123]

* Some individuals have claimed that the government’s indexes undercount inflation. These critics object to the following aspects of the government’s methodology:

  • The goods included in the indexes change along with consumer spending habits. For example, as prices increase, consumers switch to cheaper goods (such as switching from steak to hamburger). Critics claim that the government is ignoring the price increase of steak by substituting hamburger into its price index.[124] [125]
  • The indexes use the rent a homeowner could charge a tenant to measure owner-occupied housing costs. Critics say that the indexes should instead use actual house prices.[126] [127]
  • If a product’s features improve (for example, computer processing power), the indexes account for the added value of these features. Critics claim that the monetary value of such product improvements cannot be objectively measured, so such quality adjustments should not occur.[128] [129] [130]

* John Williams, founder of Shadow Government Statistics,[131] has claimed that the government undercounts inflation by 7% each year.[132]

* In 2008, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) published an article to address such criticisms. It presents the following facts:

  • CPI measures the amount of money required to maintain a constant standard of living. When substitution occurs, it is only between “close substitutes,” such as types of “apples in Chicago.” BLS “does not assume that consumers substitute hamburger for steak,” because those items are in different categories, and it would reflect a declining standard of living.[133]
  • The effects of product substitution have decreased the BLS inflation rate by an average of less than 0.3 percentage points per year.[134]
  • CPI is “designed to exclude investment items,” such as stocks and real estate, because its purpose is to measure “day-to-day consumption expenses,” not savings. Using owners’ equivalent rent means the BLS is measuring what homeowners “lose by not renting out their house.” This allows the government to include a homeowner’s cost of shelter and exclude the portion of homeownership that would be considered an investment.[135] [136]
  • Quality adjustment applies to all products’ quality increases and decreases, so it could result in either a higher or lower adjusted price. It does not “amount to zeroing out a price change because quality increased.” If BLS did not use a quality adjustment, inflation measurements could be skewed by treating “all new items as identical to those they replaced.”[137]
  • BLS adjustments based on product quality have a “very small impact” and have actually increased the BLS inflation rate by an average of 0.005% per year.[138]
  • Real-world prices do not support the claim that CPI underestimates inflation by 7% per year, which would result in a 155% cumulative inflation rate from 1998 to 2008. For example:
    • The average price of a gallon of whole milk rose from $2.67 in April 1998 to $3.80 in April 2008. A 155% cumulative inflation rate during that time would have resulted in a price of $6.81.
    • During the same time, the price of a two-liter bottle of non-diet cola rose from $1.06 to $1.33. A 155% price increase would have resulted in a price of $2.72.
    • Out of 10 prices evaluated in the article, “only two—gasoline and fuel oil—increased by such a large percentage” during that period.[139]

* The Billion Prices Project is a non-government academic program that tracks price trends.[140] Its data—collected daily from thousands of online sources—shows a close correlation with government inflation data.[141]


Effects

* Inflation or deflation is most damaging if it changes rapidly and unexpectedly, which can inflict serious damage on an economy.[142] [143]

* Unexpected inflation may hurt consumers because prices on goods can change daily, but wages do not always adjust immediately.[144]

* Unexpected inflation can hurt lenders, who are repaid with money worth less than when the terms of the loan were negotiated. This benefits borrowers because they repay their debts with less valuable money.[145]

* Since unexpected inflation can hurt lenders, it may make financial institutions less willing to make loans, particularly long-term loans.[146]

* Inflation also causes:

  • menu costs, which is the extra money businesses must spend on new menus and catalogs because they need to update prices more frequently.
  • shoe leather costs, which refers to the extra time people spend shopping to search for bargains.[147]
  • relative price volatility, which happens when some companies raise prices and others keep their prices the same in order to avoid menu costs.[148]
  • deadweight loss, which is the loss that consumers experience from holding cash that is losing value.[149] [150]

* During deflation, borrowers are less willing to take out loans because they will repay the lender with more valuable money.[151]

* Spending goes down during periods of deflation, because consumers wait for prices to drop even lower before making purchases or investments.[152] [153]

* Reduced spending and dropping prices cause lower sales and profits. Lower demand for workers, and workers being unwilling to take pay cuts, can cause higher levels of unemployment.[154] [155]

* In periods of falling prices, the Federal Reserve takes action to reduce private-sector interest rates by reducing the federal funds rate—the interest rate banks charge each other for short-term loans. Lower interest rates encourage more borrowing and spending. This increases demand for products, which then leads to increased prices and wages.[156] [157]

* If the federal funds rate is near zero and there is still deflation, the Federal Reserve may employ quantitative easing. This means the Federal Reserve creates new money to purchase large quantities of assets, such as mortgage-related investments and federal bonds.[158] [159] In 2010, Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke said these purchases were made to “improve market functioning and to push longer-term interest rates lower.”[160] [161]

* The Federal Reserve used quantitative easing during the Great Depression of the 1930s and the Great Recession that began in 2007.[162] [163] [164] [165]

Gold Standard and Fiat Money

* A gold standard is a monetary system that defines a country’s currency as a fixed amount of gold. The government promises to exchange its currency into gold at a fixed rate.[166]

* If a country’s currency is not convertible into a commodity like gold, it is fiat money. Fiat money has value because a government declares that it is legal tender. The dollar’s status as legal tender is further supported by laws that requires tax debts to be paid in dollars. Its value is not tied to a commodity such as gold or silver.[167] [168]

* Historically, English money was known as “sterling,” and starting in the 10th century, 240 silver pennies made up one “pound sterling.”[169] In 1717, the United Kingdom’s Master of the Mint, Sir Isaac Newton, defined the pound sterling’s value in terms of gold rather than silver for the first time.[170]

* During the American Revolution, the Continental Congress issued paper money known as the “Continental.” It was not defined in terms of any precious metal and was easily counterfeited. Thus, it quickly lost its purchasing power, giving rise to the expression “not worth a Continental.”[171] [172]

* Starting with the Coinage Act of 1792, the United States used a bimetallic currency standard. This means the dollar was defined by its value in both silver and gold.[173]

* In December 1861, the United States suspended its link to a metal standard due to the costs of the Civil War.[174] Its currency was therefore fiat during this period.[175] In 1879, the U.S. government resumed converting paper currency into gold.[176] [177]

* In the early 19th century, Britain officially adopted the gold standard.[178] During the 1870s, Germany, Holland, Austro-Hungary, Russia, Scandinavia, and France also switched to the gold standard.[179]

* In 1900, the United States officially adopted the gold standard with the Gold Standard Act.[180]

* The period from 1880 to the outbreak of World War I in 1914 is known as the “classical gold standard era.”[181] During that time:

  • most major countries adhered to a gold standard.[182]
  • there was strong growth among the major economies, with low inflation and expanded free trade.[183] [184]
  • exchange rates between countries were fixed because each country valued its currency in relation to gold.[185]
  • trade deficits between nations were often settled with gold.[186]

* During World War I, many countries suspended the gold standard and began printing money to finance the war effort, which led to high inflation.[187] By 1919, the United States was the only world power that still followed the gold standard.[188]

* After World War I, Britain and other European countries briefly returned to the gold standard.[189] During the Gold Exchange Era of 1925–1931, countries agreed to keep a supply of gold, U.S. dollars, or British pounds. The United States and United Kingdom agreed to hold gold.[190] [191]

* Britain left the gold standard in 1931 amidst the Great Depression, and the value of British money dropped significantly.[192] [193] Other nations that relied heavily on Britain for trade then dropped the gold standard to prevent Britain’s weak currency from pricing their “goods out of the large market which Britain provided.”[194]

* In 1944, delegates from 44 nations met in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to establish a new international monetary system. These countries agreed to value their currencies according to the U.S. dollar for international trade. In turn, the U.S. dollar would keep a fixed value of $35 per ounce of gold.[195]

* The Bretton Woods system required the United States to maintain a large supply of gold. In 1971, Republican President Richard Nixon ended the dollar’s link to gold.[196] Per the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond:

Except during periods of global crisis, this was the first time in history that most of the monies of the industrialized world were on an irredeemable paper money standard.[197]

* When the final gold link was severed in August 1971, the U.S. dollar and all other world currencies became fiat. Thus, their values began to rise and fall against one another based on supply and demand, financial speculation, and government currency manipulation.[198] [199]


Inflation Trends

NOTE: When interpreting the facts in this section, It is important to realize that association does not prove causation, and it is often difficult to determine causation in economics and other social sciences. This is because numerous variables might affect a certain outcome, and there is frequently no objective way to identify all of these factors and isolate the interplay between them.

* Under a strict gold standard, the amount of money in a country’s economy was determined by the amount of gold the government had in its possession. Prices were expected to remain stable if gold production kept up with the economy’s demand for money.[200] [201]

* Unexpected changes in the supply of gold were associated with short-term price instability.[202] [203] However, annual inflation rates in economies on a gold standard had long-term price stability.[204]

* When a country’s currency is fiat, the monetary policies of its central bank affect inflation. The Federal Reserve is responsible for deciding the amount of money in circulation and “maintaining confidence” in the currency’s value.[205] [206] [207] [208]

* During the classical gold standard era (1880–1914), the annual inflation rate in the U.S. averaged about 0.2% per year. From 1972 (after the end of the Bretton Woods System) to 2017, the average annual inflation rate was 4.0%:

Inflation Rates

[209]

Exchange Rates

* Exchange rates—the prices of one currency in relation to others—play an important role in a country’s trade performance. They have large impacts on international trade and overall financial performance.[210] [211] For example:

  • If a country’s currency becomes more valuable in relation to other currencies, its goods become more expensive for other countries to import. This can lower international demand for its products, which reduces its exports and can cause unemployment. Since other countries’ goods are less expensive, its imports may increase.[212] [213] [214]
  • If a country’s currency becomes less valuable in relation to other currencies, its goods become cheaper to other countries. This increases its exports and lowers unemployment. The International Monetary Fund estimates that a 10% drop in currency value is associated with an increase in net exports worth between 0.5% and 3.1% of GDP.[215] [216]
  • Exchange rate volatility causes risk and higher costs in international transactions, because the value of a contract can change in the middle of the transaction process.[217]

* A country can influence exchange rates and its ratio of imports to exports by changing the value of its currency. In 1934, the U.S. reduced the dollar’s value in terms of gold by 69%. In 1949, the U.K. devalued the pound by 30%. In each of these cases, devaluing the currency encouraged exports by making the country’s goods cheaper for other countries to buy.[218] [219] [220] [221]

* When two countries’ currencies are defined in terms of the same material, such as gold, their exchange rate is fixed.[222] [223] For example, when the United States dollar and British pound were both valued in gold during the classical gold standard era (1880–1914), the exchange rate for £1 stayed steady at $4.86.[224]

* When countries do not have a common standard of value for their currencies, their exchange rates float. This means they fluctuate based on supply and demand, financial speculation, and government currency manipulation.[225]

* Since 1792, the U.S. dollar and British pound have alternated nine times between fixed exchange rates under the gold standard and floating exchange rates. During these periods, the British pound’s value against the dollar fluctuated as follows:

Dollar–Pound Exchange Rate

[226] [227] [228]

* In the centuries before 1971, the major economies generally used gold and silver coins for currency, and later, paper money backed by stockpiles of the precious metals.[229]

* In 1944, the Bretton Woods system was established with the U.S. dollar defined at $35 per ounce of gold. All other member countries set fixed exchange rates to the dollar.[230]

* In the 1960s, the U.S. struggled to maintain its role in the Bretton Woods system due to rising spending and inflation. In 1971, Republican President Richard Nixon suspended the government’s policy of exchanging dollars for gold in international markets, to stop the outflow of its gold supply. Within two years, exchange rates began to fluctuate.[231]

* Since 1973, member countries of the International Monetary Fund have chosen their own exchange rate systems. None of these countries are tied to a gold standard.[232]

* The International Monetary Fund (IMF) defines these exchange rate systems as:

  • hard peg—a nation replaces its own currency with a foreign currency, or fixes its currency’s value to a foreign currency. It has no independent monetary policy of its own. Such regimes are usually stable and durable.[233]
  • soft peg—a nation maintains a somewhat stable exchange rate with one currency or a group of currencies, and maintains an independent monetary policy. These tend not to be long lasting and may be vulnerable to financial crises.[234]
  • floating—a nation’s central bank has an independent monetary policy and exchange rates are market-determined. Most advanced countries, including the United States, are floating systems.[235]
  • other—a nation’s exchange rate system does not fit into the other categories, or often shifts between categories.[236]

* According to a 2016 report, the IMF has 189 member nations plus two territories and Hong Kong. It classifies their exchange rate systems as follows:[237]

  • Hard peg – 25 members (13%).
  • Soft peg – 76 members (40%).
  • Floating – 71 members (37%).
  • Other – 20 members (10%).[238] [239]

Federal Reserve

History

* During the Revolutionary War, the Continental Congress printed paper currency to finance the war. The currency was not backed by precious metal and was easily counterfeited. It quickly lost value, leading to the saying “not worth a Continental.”[240]

* The Constitution gave Congress sole power to coin money. In 1792, Congress passed the Coinage Act, which established the first mint and a system of silver and gold coins.[241]

* Treasury Secretary Alexander Hamilton proposed the creation of a national bank in order to support a stable currency and access to loans. In 1791, the First Bank of the United States opened in Philadelphia.[242]

* The bank was authorized by Congress to hold $10 million in capital. It was mostly owned by private interests but was directed to serve a public purpose.[243] It made loans, accepted deposits, sold U.S. government bonds, and issued paper currency backed by gold and silver.[244]

* In 1811, Congress did not renew the bank’s charter. Opponents of the national bank considered the bank unconstitutional and felt it infringed on states’ rights.[245] [246]

* From 1811 to 1816, state banks expanded and issued a wide variety of currencies.[247] These banks stopped backing their paper currencies with silver and gold, and the large volume of money that entered the economy caused the currencies to lose value. In order to fund the War of 1812, the federal government incurred large debts because the money it had lost its purchasing power.[248] [249]

* In 1816, Congress chartered the Second Bank of the United States. This bank redeemed state-issued paper money for gold and silver, which helped stem inflation.[250] [251] President Andrew Jackson called the bank unconstitutional, and in 1836 he vetoed its re-charter.[252]

* The years from 1837 to 1863 are called the Free Banking Era. Private, state-chartered banks issued their own paper currency without federal regulation. Although banks needed to follow state laws, government permission was not needed to open a bank.[253] [254] [255]

* The National Banking Act of 1863 established nationally chartered banks, which had to back their paper money with federal government bonds. The act was then amended to tax currencies issued by state banks. This reduced the amount of state-issued paper money and left the country with a uniform currency.[256] [257]

* From the end of the Civil War in 1865 to 1907, a series of bank panics caused many banks to fail. These panics occurred when a large number of customers withdrew their money out of fear that banks would run out of money.[258] [259] [260]

* In contrast, Canadian banks remained stable during this period and again during the series of bank failures and panics that struck the United States in the 1920s and 1930s. Canadian banks were able to create multiple branches nationwide, which allowed them to spread risk across different markets. State-chartered banks in the United States were not allowed to cross state lines, and in some states, they were not allowed to create any branches.[261] [262] [263]

* Attempts in the United States to mirror the Canadian banking model failed until the 1980s, and full nationwide branch banking was not allowed until 1994. Groups such as farmers and small banks feared that branch banking would negatively affect their interests, and they argued that interstate banking violates states’ constitutional rights.[264] [265]

* In response to a bank panic in 1907, Congress established a Monetary Commission in 1908. The commission, led by Republican Senator Nelson Aldrich, made a plan to create a new central bank. The plan was criticized by progressives for giving control to bankers rather than the public.[266]

* The Aldrich plan was abandoned in 1912 when Democrat Woodrow Wilson, a founder of modern liberalism, became president  of the U.S. In late 1913, Wilson signed the Federal Reserve Act into law, creating a system that was considered to be a balance between public interests and private banks.[267] [268]

* One provision of the Federal Reserve Act gave member banks a way to retire their paper currencies. This moved the country to a centrally controlled currency under the Federal Reserve.[269] [270] [271]

* In 1927, Congress re-chartered the Federal Reserve ahead of schedule for an unlimited term. The Great Depression, which began in the United States in 1929, soon followed.[272] [273]

* Congress updated the Federal Reserve System with laws in:

  • 1935 to create the Federal Open Market Committee, which governs monetary policy.[274]
  • 1977 to set price stability as an official goal.
  • 1978 to set full employment as a second policy goal, and to require the Fed to report to Congress twice a year.
  • 2010 to increase the Fed’s oversight and regulation of financial companies, and to establish the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau.[275]

Structure

* The Federal Reserve System is compromised of:

  • a seven-person Board of Governors, which is the central governing body that oversees the operations of the Federal Reserve Banks and the regulation of financial institutions.[276]
  • 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks, which provide banking services to commercial banks and the U.S. government.[277] [278]
  • the Federal Open Market Committee, which makes monetary policy decisions.[279]

* The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve:

  • has seven members, each of whom is nominated by the U.S. President and confirmed by the U.S. Senate. Each governor represents a different geographic region of the Federal Reserve System.[280] [281]
  • is led by the Chair of the Board, who presides at meetings and serves as the Board’s spokesperson to Congress and the public.[282] [283]

* There are 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks,[284] and each:

  • represents a particular area of the country.
  • has a nine-person board of directors responsible for the administration of the Bank, including its budget, audits, and overall goals. The board of directors includes:
    • six directors elected by member banks—three to represent banks and three to represent public interests.
    • three directors appointed by the Board of Governors, all of whom represent public interests.
    • a chair selected by the Board of Governors from one of its three appointees.
  • has a president who is nominated by the six directors representing public interests. This nominee must be approved by the Board of Governors. The president, as chief executive officer, oversees the day-to-day operations of the Reserve Bank.
  • provides banking services to its commercial bank members. The members of the Federal Reserve Banks include:
    • commercial banks chartered by the federal government, who are required to be members.
    • state-chartered commercial banks, who may choose to be members if they meet standards set by the Board of Governors.
    • a total of approximately 3,000 of the nation’s 8,039 commercial banks (38%).[285] [286] [287] [288] [289]

* The Federal Open Market Committee:

  • meets eight times per year to discuss the country’s economic conditions.
  • includes the Board of Governors and all 12 regional Reserve Bank presidents in its meetings.
  • has 12 voting members—the seven members of the Board of Governors, the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and four other Reserve Bank presidents on a rotating basis.
  • makes monetary policy decisions based on majority votes of the voting members.
  • send its decisions to the New York Federal Reserve Bank for implementation.
  • publishes a statement immediately after each meeting that explains the Committee’s decisions.
  • publishes meeting minutes three weeks after each meeting.
  • publishes full word-for-word transcripts five years after each meeting.[290] [291] [292] [293]

Who Owns the Fed?

* The Federal Reserve System is controlled by:

  • a seven-person Board of Governors, who are appointed by the U.S. President and approved by the U.S. Senate. This independent government agency is the Fed’s central governing body.
  • 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks, which are owned by 3,000 commercial member banks. These regional Banks carry out the Fed’s operations.
  • federal laws that govern the operations of the Fed.[294] [295] [296]

* The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve:

  • has seven members who:
    • are appointed by the U.S. President and confirmed by the U.S. Senate for terms of 14 years, with one position expiring every two years. The term length and rotation of positions are designed to prevent political pressure from influencing policy.[297] [298] [299]
    • may be removed from office by the President “for cause,” which is an undefined term generally understood to mean that they cannot be removed for their policy views.[300] [301] [302] [303]
    • cannot be reappointed after serving a full term.[304]
  • is led by the Chair of the Board who:
    • is appointed by the U.S. President and confirmed by the U.S. Senate for a term of four years.
    • may be reappointed to multiple terms until his or her term as governor expires.
    • presides over Board meetings, serves as the Fed’s spokesperson, and represents the Fed before Congress.[305] [306]

* The Federal Reserve’s 12 regional Reserve Banks are separately incorporated,[307] and each has a:

  • nine-person board of directors that is responsible for overseeing the administration of its Reserve Bank, including the budget, audits, and overall goals. These board members:
    • include six directors who are elected by member banks—three from the banking industry and three to represent the public interest.
    • include three directors who are appointed by the Board of Governors, all of whom represent the public interest.
    • are headed by a chair and deputy chair who are designated by the Board of Governors each year from among the Board’s appointed directors.
    • can be suspended or removed by the Board of Governors.[308] [309] [310] [311]
  • president who acts as the chief executive officer of the bank and has voting power on the Federal Open Market Committee on a rotating basis. The president:
    • is nominated by the six directors who represent the public interest and must be approved by the Board of Governors.
    • serves a term of five years and can be reappointed to multiple terms.
    • can be suspended or removed by the Board of Governors or dismissed by the Bank’s board of directors.
    • oversees the operations of the Bank, including monetary policy, regulations, and payments services.[312] [313] [314]

* Congress established the Federal Reserve’s authority in 1913.[315] The Fed is governed by federal laws, including those that require:

  • the Fed to aim for maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.[316] However, the Fed’s decisions on how to reach those goals do not require approval by Congress or the president.[317] [318]
  • all commercial banks who are members of regional Reserve Banks to hold stock in these banks. Under the law:
    • banks cannot sell or trade this stock.[319] [320] [321]
    • each Reserve Bank pays stock dividends to its members. This rate was 6% from 1913 to 2015. In 2015, this amounted to total dividends of $1.7 billion.
    • starting in January of 2016, the dividend for banks with over $10 billion in assets was changed to the lesser of 6% or the current interest rate on 10-year federal bonds. In 2017, the Reserve Banks paid a total of $784 million in dividends to its member banks.[322] [323] [324] [325] [326]
  • the Fed to publish weekly financial statements and annual reports that include policy votes and action summaries.[327]
  • an annual audit of the Fed’s financial statements by an independent outside firm.[328] [329]
  • periodic audits by the Government Accountability Office and the Board’s Office of Inspector General on some Federal Reserve activities.[330] These audits can evaluate the Fed for waste, fraud, and abuse. They cannot evaluate the effectiveness of the Fed’s policies.[331]
  • the Federal Reserve to finance its own activities, rather than relying on Congressional outlays. Under this law, the Fed:
    • pays for its operations with interest earned on the assets it purchases—such as government bonds, mortgage-related investments, and federal agency debt—and the fees it collects for its services.[332] [333]
    • is required to give its net earnings to the U.S. Treasury.[334] [335]
    • submitted approximately $80 billion to the U.S. Treasury in 2017.[336]

* In 2017, Representative Thomas Massie introduced the Federal Reserve Transparency Act. It would allow audits on areas of the Fed that are currently restricted, including policy decisions and international transactions.[337]


Functions

* The Federal Reserve System has five main responsibilities. It is tasked to:

  1. conduct monetary policy.
  2. maintain the stability of the financial system and contain risks to financial markets.
  3. monitor and regulate financial institutions.
  4. provide financial services to the banking industry and U.S. government.
  5. promote consumer protection.[338] [339]

* “Monetary policy” refers to the Fed’s actions to achieve three goals set by Congress: maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. These actions directly affect short-term interest rates, which also affect the flow of credit in the economy.[340]

* Monetary policy indirectly affects stock prices, wealth, and exchange rates, which in turn influence spending, investment, production, employment, and inflation.[341]

* The Federal Open Market Committee sets goals for the federal funds rate, an influential short-term interest rate.[342] [343] The New York Federal Reserve Bank implements the policy by buying or selling government bonds in the open market.[344]

* When the Federal Open Market Committee seeks to encourage more economic activity, it purchases government bonds and deposits the payments into the bank accounts of the sellers. Because they have more money available to lend, banks loan money at lower interest rates to attract borrowers.[345]

* When the Federal Open Market Committee seeks to reduce the amount of money circulating in the economy, it sells government bonds. People or companies who buy these bonds use money from their bank accounts, so banks have less money to lend. They increase the price of loans by increasing interest rates.[346]

* The Board of Governors requires member banks to hold aside a portion of their deposits in their own vaults or at their Reserve Banks. If the Board decreases this portion, the amount of money available to loan increases, which means more money will circulate through the economy.[347]

* Banks often keep extra money aside, and the Federal Reserve pays interest on those excess funds. If the Federal Open Market Committee wants to increase the amount of money circulating in the economy, it can lower the interest rate it pays on excess bank funds. This encourages banks to lend their excess funds to make more money than if they held it aside.[348]

* The Federal Reserve Banks provide services to:

  • commercial banks by distributing currency, lending money, and processing electronic payments.
  • the U.S. government by maintaining accounts for the U.S. Treasury, processing government checks, and holding auctions for government debt.
  • the public by conducting research and distributing information about the economy, and enforcing bank compliance with consumer protection laws.[349] [350] [351]

* The interest rate that Reserve Banks charge commercial banks for short-term loans is the “discount rate.” Every two weeks, the board of each regional Reserve Bank recommends a rate, which is then set by a majority vote of the Board of Governors. Though it originally varied by region, the rate is now standard across all Reserve Banks.[352] [353] [354]

* The discount rate influences private-market interest rates. If the Fed wants to increase the amount of money circulating in the economy, it decreases the discount rate.[355]


Track Record

NOTE: When interpreting the facts in this section, It is important to realize that association does not prove causation, and it is often difficult to determine causation in economics and other social sciences. This is because numerous variables might affect a certain outcome, and there is frequently no objective way to identify all of these factors and isolate the interplay between them.

* The Federal Reserve has three priorities set by Congress in 1977: (1) maximum employment, (2) stable prices, and (3) moderate long-term interest rates.[356] [357]

* World War I began in 1914, less than one year after the Federal Reserve System was created. The war created tremendous upheaval in the international financial system, including the suspension of the international gold standard, major increases in government debt, and soaring inflation.[358] [359] [360]

* The interwar years from 1919 to 1939 were a time of financial chaos. After World War I, European nations tried to restore the pre-war gold standard but abandoned it amidst the Great Depression.[361]

* The Great Depression was more severe and longer-lasting in the United States than in many other countries. Some economists believe the Fed’s policies from 1929 to 1937 contributed to the country’s economic problems.[362] [363]

* During World War II, the Federal Reserve focused on financing the United States’ war efforts. This focus diverted the Federal Reserve from its primary mission.[364]

* The forthcoming facts about unemployment, inflation, interest rates, and economic growth cover the Federal Reserve’s tenure from 1914 (when available) to 2017. They also isolate the post-World War II period (1946–2017) to remove the impact of the two world wars and the Great Depression. When available, data from the period prior to the Fed’s creation in 1913 is also provided.


* During the Fed’s tenure, the average annual unemployment rate ranged from 1% to 25%, with a median of 5% and an average of 9%. Post-World War II, the average annual unemployment rate ranged from 3% to 10%, with a median and an average of 6%:

Unemployment Rate

[365]


* Stable prices occur when the economy is not experiencing high or unexpected rates of inflation or deflation.[366] [367] [368]

* From 1800 to the Federal Reserve’s creation in 1913, the average annual inflation rate was –0.3%.[369]

* For the Fed’s full tenure, the average annual inflation rate was 3.2%.[370]

* Post-World War II, the average annual inflation rate was 3.7%.[371]

Inflation Rates, 10-Year Rolling Average

[372]


* Low interest rates help encourage spending in the economy by making it cheaper to borrow money.[373] [374]

* For the Fed’s tenure starting in 1919, annual interest rates on long-term federal bonds ranged from 2% to 14%, with an average of 5% and a median of 4%. Post-World War II, they ranged from 2% to 14%, with an average of 6% and a median of 5%:[375]

Long-Term U.S. Treasury Yields

[376]


* Gross domestic product (GDP) measures the value of the goods and services produced by an economy during a specific time period. GDP is defined by the equation: Hours worked x Labor productivity.[377] [378]

* The growth rate of inflation-adjusted GDP is a key indicator of the health of an economy. A strong growth rate is often associated with higher rates of employment, while low or negative rates may accompany employment declines.[379]

* Average annual inflation-adjusted GDP growth was 4.0% prior to the Fed’s creation, 3.3% during the Fed’s full tenure, and 2.9% post-World War II:

Inflation-Adjusted GDP Growth, 10-Year Rolling Average

[380]

Quantitative Easing

Background

* Quantitative easing is an unconventional Federal Reserve policy implemented during the Great Depression of the 1930s and the Great Recession that began in 2007.[381] [382] [383] [384]

* The Federal Open Market Committee is the monetary policymaking body of the Federal Reserve System.[385] It sets goals for the federal funds rate, the price banks charge each other for short-term loans of their money to one another.[386] [387] [388]

* When the Federal Open Market Committee seeks to encourage more economic activity, it purchases government bonds and deposits the payments into the sellers’ bank accounts. Because they have more money available to lend, banks loan money at lower interest rates to attract borrowers.[389]

* From 1998 to 2006, home prices rose at unprecedented rates. In 2007, prices began dropping.[390] As housing prices fell, financial institutions lost money because of borrowers defaulting on mortgages. These losses had “large spillover effects” on other parts of the economy. This led to the Great Recession that began in December 2007 and ended in 2009.[391] [392] [393]

* In a financial crisis like the Great Recession of 2007–2009,[394] the Federal Open Market Committee may push the federal funds rate close to zero, such as in December 2008. Since the rate could not be reduced any further, and economic conditions did not improve, the Federal Reserve implemented quantitative easing.[395]

* During quantitative easing, the Fed created new money and bought large quantities of financial assets, such as:[396] [397]

  • long-term federal debt.
  • long-term mortgage-related investments.
  • the debt of government-sponsored agencies.[398] [399]

Purpose

* The stated purpose of quantitative easing (QE) was to reduce interest rates to encourage spending in the economy.[400]

* In January 2009, as the Fed initiated QE, then-Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke said the program’s main purpose was to make it easier and less costly for households and businesses to borrow money. “If the program works as planned,” he said, “it should lead to lower rates and greater availability of consumer and small business credit.”[401] [402] [403]

* With easier and cheaper access to credit, businesses are able to make investments, such as buying new equipment. Per an article published by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis in 2011, “over time, new business investments should bolster economic activity, create new jobs, and reduce the unemployment rate.”[404]

* By making large-scale purchases of long-term federal debt, the Fed reduced the amount of debt available for sale to the public, which placed downward pressure on interest rates.[405] [406]

* The Fed also purchased mortgage-related investments and debt from government-sponsored mortgage agencies like Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks. The purpose of these purchases was to reduce mortgage rates in order to support the housing sector.[407] [408] Chairman Bernanke said that “bringing down mortgage rates” stimulates “home-buying, construction, and related industries.”[409]

* Bernanke also stated that the Fed was “compelled” to implement QE because “many financial institutions” had incurred “substantial losses” in the housing market crash, and these firms still owned a “large quantity” of “troubled” and “illiquid assets of uncertain value.”[410] These “toxic assets” consisted largely of subprime and other high-risk mortgages that had fueled the housing crash.[411] [412] [413]

* Since financial institutions had suffered large losses and still owned stockpiles of bad investments that they could not sell without taking further losses, these firms could not effectively loan, borrow, or trade. Bernanke said this was problematic because “our economic system is critically dependent on the free flow of credit.”[414]

* In order to open the flow of credit, the Fed began purchasing groups of “toxic assets” and providing large loans to financial institutions. This provided those corporations with additional money in their bank accounts and “reduced the total amount of risky assets investors held.”[415] [416] [417]

* Chairman Bernanke said, the public “is understandably concerned by the commitment of substantial government resources to aid the financial industry,” but this action “appears unavoidable” in order to save the economy. He also noted that the “large firms that the government is now compelled to support to preserve financial stability were among the greatest risk-takers during the boom period.”[418]


Actions

* At the beginning of the Great Recession, the Federal Reserve set up an emergency lending program to stimulate the flow of money in the economy. From December 2007 to September 2008, the Fed funded loans to banks and financial firms by selling off $315 billion of its federal bonds.[419] [420]

* In September 2008, the Fed ran out of federal bonds to sell but continued to make loans by creating new money. These new loans increased the Fed’s assets from less than $1 trillion to over $2 trillion in approximately 3 months. Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke referred to this policy as “credit easing.”[421] [422]

* In November 2008, the Federal Reserve announced its plan to begin a quantitative easing program. The original plan was to purchase large amounts of mortgage-related investments and debt belonging to housing-related government-sponsored agencies like Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks. The goal was to make mortgages cheaper and more available to the public.[423]

* In March of 2009, the Fed announced its plan to expand the size and scope of its purchases to include long-term government debt. These purchases were aimed to help improve credit conditions outside of the housing industry.[424]

* From March 2009 to March 2010, during what is now called QE1, the Fed purchased:

  • $1.25 trillion in mortgage-related investments.
  • $200 billion in debt belonging to other federal agencies.
  • $300 billion in long-term federal debt.[425]

* Due to continued low inflation and economic weakness, the Federal Reserve initiated a second round of large-scale asset purchases called QE2. From November 2010 to June 2011, it purchased $600 billion of long-term federal debt.[426]

* From September 2011 to December 2012, the Fed implemented a Maturity Extension Program, which is also known as “Operation Twist.” The Fed sold short-term bonds and purchased an equal amount of long-term federal bonds. The goal was to reduce long-term interest rates without further expanding the Fed’s balance sheet.[427] [428]

* In September 2012, the Fed began QE3—a phase of large-scale asset purchases without a set end date or total cost estimate. It began purchasing $40 billion of mortgage-related investments each month, then in January 2013 added $45 billion of long-term federal bonds per month. Monthly purchases were tapered down until QE3 ended in October 2014 with a total cost of approximately $1.6 trillion.[429] [430] [431]

* The Federal Reserve’s total assets increased by over $1 trillion in late 2008 during the emergency lending program and then by another $2.5 trillion during the three stages of QE:[432] [433]

Federal Reserve Bank Total Assets

[434] [435]

* From 2010 through at least September 2017, the Fed took nearly all proceeds from its investments and rolled the money into new investments. This is why the total amount of its assets did not decline substantially in the three years after the end of QE.[436] [437] The Federal Open Market Committee provided details for reducing reinvestment in June 2017 and began implementing the plan in October 2017.[438] [439]

* In 2014, the Federal Reserve announced its “normalization” plan for “returning both short-term interest rates” and the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet “to more normal levels.”[440]

* In December 2015, the Federal Reserve raised the federal funds target rate for the first time since 2008, from about 0% to 0.25–0.5%. It incrementally continued to increase the target rate to 2–2.25% in September 2018.[441] [442] [443]


Outcomes

NOTE: When interpreting the facts in this section, It is important to realize that association does not prove causation, and it is often difficult to determine causation in economics and other social sciences. This is because numerous variables might affect a certain outcome, and there is frequently no objective way to identify all of these factors and isolate the interplay between them.


* Mortgage rates began declining when the Federal Reserve announced its plan to purchase mortgage-related investments in November of 2008, even though it had not made any purchases yet.[444] [445]

* Over the course of quantitative easing, interest rates on:

  • 10-year federal bonds declined from 2.8% to 2.3%.
  • corporate bonds declined from 3.8% to 2.3%.
  • 30-year mortgages declined from 5.0% to 4.0%.

Long-Term Interest Rates

[446]


* Market income consists of non-government income, such as labor income, business income, and capital gains.[447]

* From 2007 to 2013, inflation-adjusted market income for the:

  • lowest 20% of households dropped by 65%.
  • 21st to 80th percentiles dropped by 33%.
  • 81st to 99th percentiles dropped by 5%.
  • top 1% dropped by 32%.[448]
Inflation-Adjusted Household Market Income Growth Since 1979

 [449]

* The Federal Reserve’s Survey of Consumer Finances measures inflation-adjusted family net worth—“the difference between families’ gross assets and their liabilities.”[450]

* From 2007 to 2010, the median net worth for all families declined 40%, and there was little change from 2010 to 2013.[451]

* According to data from the 2016 Survey of Consumer Finances, only the top 10% of families recovered their net worth lost during the Great Recession:

Change in Median Inflation-Adjusted Family Net Worth by Wealth Group

[452]


* In 2009, the annual inflation rate according to the consumer price index dropped below zero to –0.4%. Inflation since 2010 has been positive, which offset fears of a deflationary crisis.[453] [454]

* Some economists worried that the money created during QE would cause high inflation.[455] [456] However, from 2010 to 2017, the average inflation rate was lower than the 10-year rolling average over the preceding 4 decades:

Post-World War II Inflation Rates, 10-Year Rolling Average

[457]

* Inflation likely remained low because the newly created money stayed in banks’ reserves and was not circulated into the economy. If banks begin loaning out these funds, the money supply will expand, and inflation may increase.[458] [459] [460]


* In 2009, inflation-adjusted GDP contracted at a rate of –2.5%.[461]

* The average annual inflation-adjusted GDP growth since 2010 has been 2.2%. The post-World War II average annual rate was 3.2% from 1946 to 2007.[462]

* From 2006 through 2017, inflation-adjusted economic growth did not reach 3% in any year:

Inflation-Adjusted GDP Growth

[463]


* In 2009, the unemployment rate was about 9%. In 2010, it was about 10%.[464]

* From 2010 to 2016, the annual unemployment rate ranged from 5% to 10%, with a median and average of 7%:

Recent Unemployment Rates

[465]

* Employment is also measured by the employment–population ratio, which is the percentage of the population 16 years old and over that is currently working.[466] In 2007, the annual employment–population ratio was 63%.[467]

* From 2009 to 2017, the annual employment–population ratio ranged from 58% to 60%, with a median and average of 59%. Its lowest point, 58%, occurred in 2011.[468]

* In 2017, the annual employment–population ratio was 60%, so the ratio of employment in the U.S. was still below its pre-Great Recession level.[469]


* The Dow Jones industrial average reached a record high in October 2007. That month, its inflation-adjusted average was 16,813.[470] [471]

* During the Great Recession, it declined to an inflation-adjusted monthly average of 8,391 in February 2009.[472] [473]

* In October 2014, as QE ended, its inflation-adjusted average was 18,469.[474] [475]

Inflation-Adjusted Dow Jones Industrial Average

[476]

Politicians

Ronald Reagan

* During his campaign for the 1980 presidential election, Republican Ronald Reagan called for a return to the gold standard.[477] He was quoted as believing that “no great nation in history that went off the gold standard remained great.”[478]

* President Reagan supported the creation of the U.S. Gold Commission, which in 1982 recommended against restoring the gold standard.[479]

* He publicly supported the Federal Reserve’s unpopular policy decisions during the recession of 1981–82. These policies effectively ended The Great Inflation.[480] [481] [482] [483]


Ron Paul

* In 1980, Congress voted to create the U.S. Gold Commission to study whether to reinstate a gold standard in the United States. Senator Jesse Helms (R-NC) and Rep. Ron Paul (R-TX) sponsored the measure.[484]

* The commission majority report rejected restoring a monetary link between the dollar and gold.[485] The commission’s minority report, co-authored by Rep. Paul, argued for restoring a gold link. The report was released as a book, The Case for Gold.[486] [487]

* In 2011, he sponsored a bill to repeal the Federal Reserve Act and abolish the Federal Reserve Board and banks.[488]

* He highlighted his critique of the Federal Reserve during his runs for president and authored the book End the Fed.[489] [490]


Jack Kemp

* Jack Kemp (R-NY) was a congressman, Housing secretary, and 1996 vice presidential candidate who advocated using the price of gold to guide monetary policy.[491] [492]

* In 1984, he introduced legislation to define the dollar relative to gold and require the Treasury to exchange gold for dollars.[493]


Bill Clinton

* President Bill Clinton, a Democrat, nominated Reagan appointee Alan Greenspan to a third term as Federal Reserve chairman in 1996.[494] In 2000, President Clinton nominated Greenspan again.[495]

* In 1993, the Clinton administration made a policy not to comment on or interfere with the Federal Reserve’s policies and actions.[496] [497]

* In 1994, President Clinton signed the Riegle–Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act into law. This law made it easier for banks to open branches and acquire other banks across state lines. He praised the act for helping banks “better meet the needs of our people.”[498]


Steve Forbes

* Steve Forbes, the editor of Forbes magazine, ran for president as a Republican in 1996 and 2000, advocating for using the gold price to guide U.S. monetary policy.[499] [500] [501]

* He critiques monetary and exchange rates policy in his column, and in 2014 released the book Money: How the Destruction of the Dollar Threatens the Global Economy—and What We Can Do About It.[502] [503]


Chuck Schumer

* Senate Minority Leader Charles “Chuck” Schumer (D-NY) was disappointed in 2017 when Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen was not nominated for a second term. He previously advocated for her original nomination in 2013.[504] [505]

* He supported Ben Bernanke’s nomination as chairman in 2005 and later applauded Bernanke’s “steady hand” during the financial crisis.[506] [507]

* In 2014, he stated that the Federal Reserve should “be careful” about raising interest rates because of the “overwhelming problem” of slow job growth.[508]

* He has voted against the “Audit the Fed” bill.[509]


Newt Gingrich

* As a candidate for the Republican presidential nomination in 2011, former Speaker of the House Newt Gingrich heavily criticized the Federal Reserve. He partially blamed the Federal Reserve Board for the Great Recession and weak recovery. He also promised to fire its leadership, demand a full audit, and limit their mandate.[510] [511] [512]

* He advocated creating a gold commission—similar to the one convened under President Reagan—to consider reinstating a gold standard.[513]

* In a February 2018 commentary, he warned that the Fed’s attitude and policies will obstruct economic growth.[514]


Barack Obama

* In 2009, President Barack Obama, a Democrat, nominated Ben Bernanke for a second term as Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board. Bernanke was first appointed by Republican President George W. Bush.[515]

* At the end of Bernanke’s term, President Obama nominated Janet Yellen as Chairwoman of the Federal Reserve Board.[516]

* During his tenure, President Obama defended the Fed’s quantitative easing program.[517] His administration opposed the 2015 “Audit the Fed” legislation.[518] [519]


Paul Ryan

* In 2008, Rep. Paul Ryan (R-WI) proposed legislation to set price stability as the Fed’s sole long-term goal, which would eliminate full employment from the Fed’s dual mandate.[520]

* In 2009, he wrote that the Federal Reserve should base monetary policy on a set of “commodities” or should “explicitly embrace inflation” goals.[521]


Nancy Pelosi

* In 2013, Rep. Nancy Pelosi (D-CA) supported Janet Yellen’s nomination as Chairwoman of the Federal Reserve, and in 2017 praised Yellen’s tenure. Pelosi called on Yellen’s successor, Jerome Powell, to continue Yellen’s policies.[522] [523]

* She opposes “Audit the Fed” bills, saying in a 2012 press conference that Congress should not monitor the Federal Reserve “in terms of monetary policy.”[524]


Rand Paul

* Senator Rand Paul (R-KY) has criticized the Federal Reserve’s actions during the financial crisis. In 2016, he wrote that the Fed’s power has been “unchecked” and “arguably unconstitutional.”[525]

* He proposed legislation in 2011, 2013, 2015, and 2017 entitled the Federal Reserve Transparency Act and commonly known as “Audit the Fed.” Each version of the bill would require the Government Accountability Office to complete an audit of the Federal Reserve Board and Federal Reserve banks.[526] [527] [528] [529]


Bernie Sanders

* Senator Bernie Sanders (I-VT) has criticized the Federal Reserve, calling it a “rigged economic system.” In 2015—when he was a candidate for the Democratic presidential nomination—he wrote that the Fed should undergo a “full and independent audit” every year. He further wrote that “banking industry executives” serving on the Fed’s boards have “conflicts of interest” and should be replaced with “representatives from all walks of life.”[530]

* He has also criticized actions of the Fed. For example, he disagreed with the Fed’s decision to begin raising interest rates in 2015 while unemployment was still over 4%. Rather than paying interest to banks, he proposed that the Fed should charge the banks “a fee that would be used to provide direct loans to small businesses.”[531]


Ted Cruz

* Senator Ted Cruz (R-TX) cosponsored the 2013 and 2015 “Audit the Fed” bills.[532] [533]

* During a November 2015 Republican presidential debate, Senator Cruz referred to the Federal Reserve as “philosopher kings” and called for “sound money and monetary stability, ideally tied to gold.”[534]

* In a December 2015 hearing with Chairwoman Janet Yellen, Senator Cruz blamed the Federal Reserve’s policies for the 2008 financial crisis.[535]


Kevin Brady

* In 2015, Rep. Kevin Brady (R-TX) introduced a bill that would establish a Centennial Monetary Commission. The Commission would assess the Federal Reserve’s historical impact on the U.S. economy and recommend policies for the future.[536]

* In 2012, he proposed the Sound Dollar Act, which would have limited the Fed’s priorities to promoting long-term price stability and establishing a way to measure whether that goal is achieved.[537]


Bill Huizenga

* U.S. Rep. Bill Huizenga (R-MI) proposed the Fed Oversight Reform and Modernization (FORM) Act of 2015. It would require the Federal Reserve to adopt a rules-based monetary policy of its choosing. The Fed could stop following the rule, provided it explains its decision to Congress.[538]


Donald Trump

* As a 2016 presidential candidate, Donald Trump criticized the Federal Reserve, saying that it had created “a big, fat, ugly bubble,” and was supporting “a very false economy” with its policies.[539]

* In a 2015 interview, he stated that the United States used to be solid “because it was based on a gold standard.” He also stated that it would be difficult to implement the gold standard “at this point” because “we do not have the gold.”[540]

* In 2017, President Trump named Jerome Powell to chair the Federal Reserve. Powell is expected to continue the policies put in place by his predecessors.[541] [542]

* Since taking office, President Trump has repeatedly said he doesn’t like a “strong” dollar, meaning he doesn’t want the exchange rate to rise excessively.[543] [544]

Footnotes

[1] Entry: “Money.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

“A commodity accepted by general consent as a medium of economic exchange. It is the medium in which prices and values are expressed; as currency, it circulates anonymously from person to person and country to country, thus facilitating trade, and it is the principal measure of wealth.”

[2] Textbook: Macroeconomics (6th edition). By N. Gregory Mankiw. Worth Publishers, 2006.

Pages 77–78:

Money has three purposes. It is a store of value, a unit of account, and a medium of exchange.

As a store of value, money is a way to transfer purchasing power from the present to the future. If I work today and earn $100, I can hold the money and spend it tomorrow, next week, or next month. Of course, money is an imperfect store of value: if prices are rising, the amount you can buy with any given quantity of money is falling. Even so, people hold money because they can trade the money for goods and services for some time in the future.

As a unit of account, money provides the terms in which prices are quoted and debts are recorded. Microeconomics teaches us that resources are allocated according to relative prices—the prices of good relative to other goods—yet stores post their prices in dollars and cents. A car dealer tells you that a car costs $20,000, not 400 shirts (even though it may amount to the same thing). Similarly, most debts require the debtor to deliver a specified number of dollars in the future, not a specified amount of some commodity. Money is the yardstick with which we measure economic transactions.

As a medium of exchange, money is what we use to buy goods and services. “This note is legal tender for all debts, public and private” is printed on the U.S. dollar. When we walk into stores, we are confident that the shopkeepers will accept our money in exchange for the items they are selling.

[3] Webpage: “All About Money.” European Commission. Accessed June 3, 2018 at <ec.europa.eu>

“Many thousands of years ago, our European ancestors lived as hunters and farmers. They did not have the banknotes and coins that we use today. Instead, they would exchange goods with each other: for example, a hunter could exchange animal skins with a farmer for grain, or a fisherman could exchange decorative seashells for a polished stone axe with a hunter. This exchange is known as barter.”

[4] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Pages 9–10:

Throughout by far the greater part of man’s development, barter necessarily constituted the sole means of exchanging goods and services. …

Commodities were chosen as preferred barter items for a number of reasons—some because they were conveniently and easily stored, some because they had high value densities and were easily portable, some because they were more durable (or less perishable).

[5] Webpage: “The Story of Money: 02—Common Products as Money.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Accessed August 8, 2017 at <www.frbatlanta.org>

“Trading everyday items made barter easier. It reconciled the wants of buyer and seller, simplified payments, and introduced standard measures. Common goods used in trade are known as commodity money. Cows as a form of money … Tea as a form of money … Raw metals as a form of money.”

[6] Webpage: “The Story of Money: 03—Value in Use, Value in Exchange.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Accessed August 8, 2017 at <www.frbatlanta.org>

In some forms, money has value in use: you can eat or wear it, chop wood with it, or use it to make something else. In other forms, money has value in exchange: it works because we agree that the money represents a certain value. The silver in this “tiger tongue” made it intrinsically valuable. This Luristan bronze arm ring is a 7,000-year-old form of money. Dried grain was useful as money and food. Arrowheads were popular in trade. Throwing knives were used in the Congo as tools and money. Cowrie shell necklaces were used for jewelry and exchange. Kissi pennies are still used in parts of West Africa.

[7] Textbook: Macroeconomics (6th edition). By N. Gregory Mankiw. Worth Publishers, 2006.

Page 78: “To better understand the functions of money, try to imagine an economy without it: a barter economy. In such a world, trade requires the double coincidence of wants—the unlikely happenstance of two people each having a good that the other wants at the right time and place to make an exchange. A barter economy permits only simple transactions.”

[8] Webpage: “Cowry Shells, a Trade Currency.” By Ingrid Van Damme. Museum of the National Bank of Belgium, January 11, 2007. <www.nbbmuseum.be>

Long before our era the cowry shell was known as an instrument of payment and a symbol of wealth and power. This monetary usage continued until the 20th century. …

The cowry which is indigenous in the warm waters of the Indian and Pacific Oceans travelled by land and by sea and gradually spread out its realm. It became the most commonly used means of payment of the trading nations of the Old World. The cowry was accepted in large parts of Asia, Africa, Oceania and in some scattered places in Europe. Chinese bronze objects, the oldest dating back to the 13th century B.C., inform us about this monetary usage. This tradition has also left its traces in the written Chinese language.

[9] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 46: “The Chinese at the end of the Stone Age began for instance to manufacture both bronze and copper ‘cowries’; and these dumpy imitations, which must have represented very high values at least when they were first introduced, are considered by some numismatists to be among the earliest examples of quasi-coinage, although this depends on how strictly one defines the term.”

Page 56: “We have already noted how metal cowries, of bronze or copper, were cast in China as symbols of objects already long accepted as money. A similar process took place with regard to spades, hoes and adzes (variants of the most common tools) and also of knives. The common characteristic of all these metallic moneys was not only that they were cast but that they were almost invariably composed of base metals.”

[10] Article: “The Importance of the Lydian Stater as the World’s First Coin.” By Everett Millman. Ancient History Encyclopedia, March 27, 2015. <www.ancient.eu>

The Lydian Stater was the official coin of the Lydian Empire, introduced before the kingdom fell to the Persian Empire. The earliest staters are believed to date to around the second half of the 7th century BCE, during the reign of King Alyattes (r. 619–560 BCE). According to a consensus of numismatic historians, the Lydian stater was the first coin officially issued by a government in world history and was the model for virtually all subsequent coinage.

[11] Webpage: “The Origins of Coinage.” British Museum. Accessed August 8, 2017 at <www.britishmuseum.org>

The earliest coins are found mainly in the parts of modern Turkey that formed the ancient kingdom of Lydia, but are made from a naturally occurring mixture of gold and silver called electrum. …

Although irregular in size and shape, these early electrum coins were minted according to a strict weight-standard. The denominations ranged from one stater (weighing about 14.1 grams) down through half-staters, thirds, sixths, twelfths, 1/24ths and 1/48ths to 1/96th stater (about 0.15gm).

[12] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 66:

From its birthplace in Lydia and Ionia the knowledge and use of coins spread rapidly east into the Persian empire and west through the rest of the Ionian and Aegean islands to mainland Greece, and then to its western colonies, especially Sicily. It also spread northward to Macedonia, Thrace and the Black Sea, but it was only partially, reluctantly and belatedly accepted in Egypt. Mainland Italy also was at first rather slow in accepting the Greek financial innovations, in contrast to the speed with which they were adopted by Sicily. Apart from these two limited exceptions of mainland Italy and Lower Egypt, the use of coinage spread rapidly around the countries bordering the central and eastern Mediterranean and over the widespread and growing Persian empire through Mesopotamia into India. …

The rapid eastward spread of coins from Lydia was not so much because of Lydian traders going east but rather a case of the spoils of war through the Persians moving quickly west.

[13] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Pages 106–107:

Shortly following Diocletian’s abdication in 305 Constantine took over an initially disputed control of much of the western empire in 306, and eventually established his authority throughout the empire…. Early in Constantine’s reign he issued a coin that is in some ways the most famous single coin in history—the gold solidus, which was to be produced, at a rate of 72 to the pound weight, for some seven hundred years. No other coin has remained pure and unchanged in weight for anything like so long a period, for when Rome fell it continued to be issued from the Byzantine capital….

[14] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 125: “The first true English penny … thus dates from 765. However, it was Offa’s conquest of Kent … that enabled Offa so to increase the production of these magnificent coins that their fame soon spread all over northern Europe….”

[15] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Pages 143–144:

Henry [II]’s reform restored the prestige of English money, the quality of which was jealously safeguarded from any further major decline until the mid-sixteenth century. This was so unlike the situation on the Continent that the term “the pound sterling” emerged into common usage with its well-known praiseworthy connotations. …

… Hence “sterling” would be the natural description for English money, which from the tenth century onward tended generally to be of higher quality than that of its continental neighbours, and therefore referred specifically to the penny coins weighing 22 1/2 grains troy of silver at least pure to 925 parts in a thousand, 240 of which made the Tower pound weight or the pound sterling in value. It is also significant to note that the term “pound sterling” was in common use throughout Europe in the Middle Ages, with all its connotations of solidity, stability and quality—long before the issue of a pound coin—when silver was almost the only metal used in British coinage and the penny was almost the only, and certainly the main, coin. … So long as full-bodied gold and silver coins were issued in Britain, that is right up to the First World War, so long did the term “the pound sterling” maintain its prestigious significance, that is for a period spanning well over 800 years, from 1078 to 1914.

[16] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 174: “Sterling was therefore much more widely used than simply within the domestic economy, being a preferred silver currency over much of northern Europe, though playing very much a secondary role in international trade when compared with the gold florins of Florence or Ghent, or the ducats of Venice.”

[17] Webpage: “Paper Money, a Chinese Invention?” By Coralie Boeykens. Museum of the National Bank of Belgium, September 5, 2007. <www.nbbmuseum.be>

During the Song Dynasty (960–1276) booming business in the region of Tchetchuan likewise resulted in a shortage of copper money. Some merchants issued private drafts covered by a monetary reserve which initially consisted of coins and salt, later of gold and silver. Those notes are considered to be the first to circulate as legal tender. …

It is hardly surprising that it took a few more centuries before paper money was introduced in Europe. In fact, if we keep to the concept of paper money as notes issued with a monetary reserve as a warranty, the first Chinese notes date from the 10th century. Which means a headstart of no less than seven centuries on the West!

[18] Entry: “Dollar.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

The word itself is a modified form of the Germanic word thaler, a shortened form of Joachimst(h)aler, the name of a silver coin first struck in 1519 under the direction of the count of Schlick, who had appropriated a rich silver mine discovered in St. Joachimsthal (Joachim’s dale), Bohemia. These coins were current in Germany from the 16th century onward, with the various spelling modifications such as daler, dalar, daalder, and tallero. Only in 1873 was the thaler replaced by the mark as the German monetary unit.

[19] Entry: “Peso.” Encyclopedia Britannica, July 20, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

“Originally divided into eight reales, the peso subsequently became the basis of the silver coinage of the Spanish empire after the monetary reform of 1772–86. In the Americas it was called ‘piece of eight,’ or ‘Spanish milled dollar,’ and was, in fact, equivalent to the U.S. silver dollar.”

[20] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 461:

[T]he colonies continued … with a marked and growing preference for the Spanish peso minted in Mexico City and Lima and the Portuguese eight-real piece. Both these large silver coins were practically identical in weight and fineness, being based on imitation of the famous “thalers” which had been produced from the silver mines in Joachimsthal in Bohemia for centuries—hence the designations “pieces of eight” and “dollars.”

[21] Article: “A Short History of the British Pound.” By Chris Parker. World Economic Forum, June 27, 2016. <www.weforum.org>

1717

The United Kingdom defined sterling’s value in terms of gold rather than silver for the first time.

Sir Isaac Newton, as Master of the Mint, set the gold price of £4.25 per fine ounce that lasted two hundred years, except during the Napoleonic wars when gold cash payments were suspended.

[22] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 469:

That Act [the Coinage Act of 1792] officially adopted the dollar as the American unit of account (so confirming Confederate legislation). … Thirdly, the dollar was officially to be bimetallist, being defined as equivalent to 371.25 grains of silver or 24.75 grains of gold. The mint ratio was thus 15:1—a rate that in practice was found slightly to overvalue silver.

[23] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 356:

In 1816 gold became at last legally recognized as the official standard of value for the pound, though it was not until the restoration of convertibility in 1821 that the domestic gold standard was in full operation. We have also traced how the Bank of England came to be the monopolistic issuer of bank notes with a fixed fiduciary issue of £14 million and also came to hold the main gold reserves of the centralizing banking system.

[24] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 357:

[T]he major trading countries had become so favourably impressed [with Britain’s management of the gold standard] that they too gave up their flirtations with silver and bimetallism and adopted full gold standards with internal circulation of full-bodied gold coinage and more or less freely allowed imports and exports of gold, as the rules of the international gold standard system demanded. Following the new German Empire’s decision in 1871 to base its mark on gold, Holland, Austro–Hungary, Russia and the Scandinavian countries soon did likewise, while in 1878 France abandoned its bimetallic experiments in favour of gold. Thus by the end of the 1870s, without being consciously planned, the international gold standard system had fallen fittingly into place (though internally the USA still flirted with bimetallism).

[25] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Pages 498–499:

[G]old supplies helped to stimulate the world economy and led to a doubling of America’s monetary gold stock from 1890 to 1900 (and a trebling between the earlier date and 1914). This was the economic reality that moved the balance of opinion decisively away from bimetallism and led at last to the confident enactment of the Gold Standard Act of March 1900: gold monometallism had, belatedly, legally captured what was to be its most powerful convert.

[26] Webpage: “What is the Fed: History.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Accessed August 14, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

As the industrial economy expanded, the weaknesses of the nation’s decentralized banking system became more acute. … Panics and runs often occurred when customers lost confidence in their banks after hearing news of failures of other banks. … A particularly severe panic took place in 1907 that abated only when a private individual, the financier J.P. Morgan, personally intervened to arrange emergency loans for financial institutions. This episode fueled a reform movement, which prompted Congress to establish the Federal Reserve System in 1913.

[27] Article: “The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal.” By Leland Crabbe. Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

To be on the gold standard a country needed to maintain the convertibility between notes and gold and to allow gold to flow freely across its borders. In the early days of the war, Austria, Hungary, France, Germany, and Russia all went off the gold standard as they suspended specie payments and instituted legal or de facto embargoes on the export of gold by private citizens. Like the British Treasury, the governments of these warring countries exported gold and borrowed heavily to finance the war, but these tactics raised only a fraction of the large sums of money that the war required. Because new taxes did not and could not make up the difference, the continental belligerents financed a large share of the war by printing money, which caused prices to soar and complicated the return of these countries to the gold standard after the war.

[28] Article: “The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal.” By Leland Crabbe. Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 426: “In 1919, almost every country regarded the gold standard as an essential institution; but, among the world powers, only the United States could be counted as a gold-standard country. … By default, the Federal Reserve assumed the office of manager of the gold standard.”

[29] Article: “The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal.” By Leland Crabbe. Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 429: “After the war, Britain and all European countries wanted to restore the legal gold-backing for their currencies. … Although determined to restore the prewar gold parity, the British had to wait for price deflation and sterling appreciation. While they waited, the formal embargo of exports on gold protected the Bank of England’s gold reserve.”

Page 431:

On April 28, 1925, Winston Churchill, then Chancellor of the Exchequer, returned Britain to the gold standard by announcing that the Gold and Silver (Export Control) Act, which was due to expire at year-end, would not be renewed. On May 13, Parliament passed the Gold Standard Act of 1925, which obligated the Bank of England to sell gold bullion in exchange for notes at the prewar par of 77s. 10.5d. per standard ounce. At the end of 1925, thirty-nine countries had returned to par, had devalued their currency, or had achieved de facto stabilization with the dollar.

[30] Entry: “Great Depression.” By Richard H. Pells and Christina D. Romer. Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

Great Depression, worldwide economic downturn that began in 1929 and lasted until about 1939. It was the longest and most severe depression ever experienced by the industrialized Western world, sparking fundamental changes in economic institutions, macroeconomic policy, and economic theory. …

… Great Britain struggled with low growth and recession during most of the second half of the 1920s. Britain did not slip into severe depression, however, until early 1930, and its peak-to-trough decline in industrial production was roughly one-third that of the United States. …

… The British economy stopped declining soon after Great Britain abandoned the gold standard in September 1931, although genuine recovery did not begin until the end of 1932.

[31] Article: “A Short History of the British Pound.” By Chris Parker. World Economic Forum, June 27, 2016. <www.weforum.org>

1931

Sterling came off the gold standard and the pound promptly dropped considerably.

£1 equivalent to $3.69.

[32] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 389:

When sterling went off gold, almost all those countries which carried on the lion’s share of their trade with Britain followed Britain off gold—otherwise they would have priced their goods out of the large market which Britain provided. These countries included all the Commonwealth (except Canada), Ireland, the Scandinavian countries, Egypt, Iraq, Portugal and Siam (Thailand), and a number of South American countries like Argentina.

[33] Article: “The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal.” By Leland Crabbe. Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 436: “An internal run on deposits and an external demand for gold combined to assault the gold standard in the United States after the abandonment of the gold standard in Britain.”

Page 438: “In January 1934, the United States relegated gold to a subordinate role in monetary policy. On January 15, the Roosevelt Administration sent legislation to the Congress vesting title of all monetary gold in the United States in the Treasury….”

Page 439:

The shift in the focus of U.S. monetary policy toward domestic objectives culminated with the Gold Reserve Act, which greatly diminished the influence of the gold standard. While the act restored the commitment by the United States to buy gold at a fixed price, it restricted sales to those involving international settlements. Americans could no longer redeem dollars for gold. The act allowed the President to change the gold content of the dollar at any time.

[34] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 516: “Eventually in January 1934 the Gold Standard Act of 1900 was replaced by the Gold Reserve Act. This raised the official price of gold from its old level of $20.67 to $35 per fine ounce—a substantial devaluation of 69.33 per cent. In this new gold standard the internal circulation of gold was ended and all private and bank-held gold was transferred to the Treasury.”

[35] Article: “Creation of the Bretton Woods System.” By Sandra Kollen Ghizoni. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

A new international monetary system was forged by delegates from forty-four nations in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, in July 1944. … The countries agreed to keep their currencies fixed but adjustable (within a 1 percent band) to the dollar, and the dollar was fixed to gold at $35 an ounce. …

In 1958, the Bretton Woods system became fully functional as currencies became convertible. Countries settled international balances in dollars, and US dollars were convertible to gold at a fixed exchange rate of $35 an ounce. The United States had the responsibility of keeping the price of gold fixed and had to adjust the supply of dollars to maintain confidence in future gold convertibility.

[36] Article: “Creation of the Bretton Woods System.” By Sandra Kollen Ghizoni. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The 730 delegates at Bretton Woods agreed to establish two new institutions. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) would monitor exchange rates and lend reserve currencies to nations with balance-of-payments deficits. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, now known as the World Bank Group, was responsible for providing financial assistance for the reconstruction after World War II and the economic development of less developed countries.

[37] Article: “The Great Inflation.” By Michael Bryan. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

As the world’s reserve currency, the U.S. dollar had an additional problem. As global trade grew, so too did the demand for U.S. dollar reserves. For a time, the demand for U.S. dollars was satisfied by an increasing balance of payments shortfall, and foreign central banks accumulated more and more dollar reserves. Eventually, the supply of dollar reserves held abroad exceeded the U.S. stock of gold, implying that the United States could not maintain complete convertibility at the existing price of gold—a fact that would not go unnoticed by foreign governments and currency speculators.

As inflation drifted higher during the latter half of the 1960s, U.S. dollars were increasingly converted to gold, and in the summer of 1971, President Nixon halted the exchange of dollars for gold by foreign central banks. …

With the last link to gold severed, most of the world’s currencies, including the US dollar, were now completely unanchored. Except during periods of global crisis, this was the first time in history that most of the monies of the industrialized world were on an irredeemable paper money standard.

[38] Article: “The Great Inflation.” By Michael Bryan. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The Great Inflation was the defining macroeconomic period of the second half of the twentieth century. Lasting from 1965 to 1982, it led economists to rethink the policies of the Fed and other central banks. …

In 1964, inflation measured a little more than 1 percent per year. It had been in this vicinity over the preceding six years. Inflation began ratcheting upward in the mid-1960s and reached more than 14 percent in 1980. …

… The origins of the Great Inflation were policies that allowed for an excessive growth in the supply of money—Federal Reserve policies. …

… [O]ne critical and erroneous assumption to the implementation of stabilization policy of the 1960s and 1970s was that there existed a stable, exploitable relationship between unemployment and inflation. Specifically, it was generally believed that permanently lower rates of unemployment could be “bought” with modestly higher rates of inflation. …

The late 1960s and the early 1970s were a turbulent time for the US economy. President Johnson’s Great Society legislation brought about major spending programs across a broad array of social initiatives at a time when the US fiscal situation was already being strained by the Vietnam War. These growing fiscal imbalances complicated monetary policy.

In order to avoid monetary policy actions that might interfere with the funding plans of the Treasury, the Federal Reserve followed a practice of conducting “even-keel” policies. In practical terms, this meant the central bank would not implement a change in policy and would hold interest rates steady during the period between the announcement of a Treasury issue and its sale to the market. …

A more disruptive force was the repeated energy crises that increased oil costs and sapped U.S. growth. …

Motivated by a mandate to create full employment with little or no anchor for the management of reserves, the Federal Reserve accommodated large and rising fiscal imbalances and leaned against the headwinds produced by energy costs. These policies accelerated the expansion of the money supply and raised overall prices without reducing unemployment.

[39] Article: “The Great Inflation: A Historical Overview and Lessons Learned.” By David A. Lopez. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Research Division Page One Economics, October 2012. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Certain economists attribute the Great Inflation primarily to monetary policy mistakes rather than other purported causes, such as high oil prices and defense spending during the Vietnam War. In the 1960s, Fed officials—and prominent economists—generally believed expansionary monetary policy could propel the economy toward full employment. In other words, they believed that elevated levels of inflation brought about by expansionary monetary policy would be tolerable as long as the policy spurred economic growth and brought unemployment down to its natural rate. …

… The Great Inflation showed that tolerating high levels of inflation in an effort to stimulate the economy would ultimately prove detrimental.

[40] Article: “How the Fed Seeks to Influence Interest Rates.” By Charles Davidson. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economy Matters, July 11, 2017. <www.frbatlanta.org>

It mostly comes down to one number.

That number is the federal funds rate, the interest rate financial institutions charge one another for overnight loans made from balances held at Federal Reserve banks.

But when the Fed's policy-setting Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) decides to adjust the fed funds rate, not all interest rates throughout the economy change instantaneously. Rather, monetary policy is “transmitted,” through various channels, to an array of very short-term interest rates and financial market prices. These changes, in turn, ripple through the financial system to influence rates on all kinds of loans to consumers and businesses.

Simply put, when interest rates rise, people tend to borrow less and prices tend to stabilize. When interest rates fall, people and businesses tend to borrow and spend more, which can stimulate the economy.

[41] Article: “The Great Inflation.” By Michael Bryan. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

In 1979, Paul Volcker, formerly the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, became chairman of the Federal Reserve Board. When he took office in August, year-over-year inflation was running above 11 percent, and national joblessness was just a shade under 6 percent. By this time, it was generally accepted that reducing inflation required greater control over the growth rate of reserves specifically, and broad money more generally. …

Over time, greater control of reserve and money growth, while less than perfect, produced a desired slowing in inflation. This tighter reserve management was augmented by the introduction of credit controls in early 1980 and with the Monetary Control Act. Over the course of 1980, interest rates spiked, fell briefly, and then spiked again. Lending activity fell, unemployment rose, and the economy entered a brief recession between January and July. Inflation fell but was still high even as the economy recovered in the second half of 1980.

But the Volcker Fed continued to press the fight against high inflation with a combination of higher interest rates and even slower reserve growth. The economy entered recession again in July 1981, and this proved to be more severe and protracted, lasting until November 1982. Unemployment peaked at nearly 11 percent, but inflation continued to move lower and by recession’s end, year-over-year inflation was back under 5 percent. In time, as the Fed’s commitment to low inflation gained credibility, unemployment retreated and the economy entered a period of sustained growth and stability. The Great Inflation was over.

[42] Article: “Recession of 1981–82.” By Tim Sablik. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

In late 1980 and early 1981, the Fed once again tightened the money supply, allowing the federal funds rate to approach 20 percent. …

The economy officially entered a recession in the third quarter of 1981, as high interest rates put pressure on sectors of the economy reliant on borrowing, like manufacturing and construction. … As the recession worsened, Volcker faced repeated calls from Congress to loosen monetary policy, but he maintained that failing to bring down long-run inflation expectations now would result in “more serious economic circumstances over a much longer period of time” (Monetary Policy Report 1982, 67).

Ultimately, this persistence paid off. By October 1982, inflation had fallen to 5 percent and long-run interest rates began to decline.

[43] Article: “How the Fed Seeks to Influence Interest Rates.” By Charles Davidson. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economy Matters, July 11, 2017. <www.frbatlanta.org>

It mostly comes down to one number.

That number is the federal funds rate, the interest rate financial institutions charge one another for overnight loans made from balances held at Federal Reserve banks.

But when the Fed's policy-setting Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) decides to adjust the fed funds rate, not all interest rates throughout the economy change instantaneously. Rather, monetary policy is “transmitted,” through various channels, to an array of very short-term interest rates and financial market prices. These changes, in turn, ripple through the financial system to influence rates on all kinds of loans to consumers and businesses.

Simply put, when interest rates rise, people tend to borrow less and prices tend to stabilize. When interest rates fall, people and businesses tend to borrow and spend more, which can stimulate the economy.

[44] Article: “The Great Moderation.” By Craig S. Hakkio. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

“The Great Moderation from the mid-1980s to 2007 was a welcome period of relative calm after the volatility of the Great Inflation. Under the chairmanships of Volcker (ending in 1987), Greenspan (1987–2006) and Bernanke (starting in 2006), inflation was low and relatively stable, while the period contained the longest economic expansion since World War II.”

[45] Article: “The Great Recession and Its Aftermath.” By John Weinberg. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The recession and crisis followed an extended period of expansion in U.S. housing construction, home prices, and housing credit. This expansion began in the 1990s and continued unabated through the 2001 recession, accelerating in the mid-2000s. … Roughly 40 percent of net private sector job creation between 2001 and 2005 was accounted for by employment in housing-related sectors.

The expansion in the housing sector was accompanied by an expansion in home mortgage borrowing by U.S. households.

[46] Article: “The Great Recession and Its Aftermath.” By John Weinberg. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The period known as the Great Moderation came to an end when the decade-long expansion in U.S. housing market activity peaked in 2006 and residential construction began declining. In 2007, losses on mortgage-related financial assets began to cause strains in global financial markets, and in December 2007 the US economy entered a recession. … [I]n the fall of 2008, the economic contraction worsened, ultimately becoming deep enough and protracted enough to acquire the label “the Great Recession.” …

… Average home prices in the United States more than doubled between 1998 and 2006, the sharpest increase recorded in US history, and even larger gains were recorded in some regions. …

The expansion in the housing sector was accompanied by an expansion in home mortgage borrowing by US households. Mortgage debt of US households rose from 61 percent of GDP in 1998 to 97 percent in 2006.

After home prices peaked in the beginning of 2007, according to the Federal Housing Finance Agency House Price Index, the extent to which prices might eventually fall became a significant question for the pricing of mortgage-related securities because large declines in home prices were viewed as likely to lead to an increase in mortgage defaults and higher losses to holders of such securities. … Ultimately, home prices fell by over a fifth on average across the nation from the first quarter of 2007 to the second quarter of 2011. This decline in home prices helped to spark the financial crisis of 2007–08, as financial market participants faced considerable uncertainty about the incidence of losses on mortgage-related assets.

[47] “The Financial Crisis Inquiry Report.” Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, January 2011. <www.gpo.gov>

Page 215:

For 2007, the National Association of Realtors announced that the number of sales of existing homes had experienced the sharpest fall in 25 years. That year, home prices declined 9%. In 2008, they would drop a stunning 17%. Overall, by the end of 2009, prices would drop 28% from their peak in 2006. …

Mortgages in serious delinquency, defined as those 90 or more days past due or in foreclosure, had hovered around 1% during the early part of the decade, jumped in 2006, and kept climbing. By the end of 2009, 9.7% of mortgage loans were seriously delinquent.

Page 226:

Through 2007 and into 2008, as the rating agencies downgraded mortgage-backed securities and CDOs [collateralized debt obligations], and investors began to panic, market prices for these securities plunged. Both the direct losses as well as the market wide contagion and panic that ensued would lead to the failure or near failure of many large financial firms across the system. The drop in market prices for mortgage-related securities reflected the higher probability that the underlying mortgages would actually default (meaning that less cash would flow to the investors) as well as the more generalized fear among investors that this market had become illiquid. Investors valued liquidity because they wanted the assurance that they could sell securities quickly to raise cash if necessary. Potential investors worried they might get stuck holding these securities as market participants looked to limit their exposure to the collapsing mortgage market.

Pages 227–228:

The large drop in market prices of the mortgage securities had large spillover effects to the financial sector, for a number of reasons. For example … when the prices of mortgage-backed securities and CDOs fell, many of the holders of those securities marked down the value of their holdings—before they had experienced any actual losses. In addition, rather than spreading the risks of losses among many investors, the securitization market had concentrated them. …

… A set of large, systemically important firms with significant holdings or exposure to these securities would be found to be holding very little capital to protect against potential losses. And most of those companies would turn out to be considered by the authorities too big to fail in the midst of a financial crisis.

Page 255:

When the mortgage market collapsed and financial firms began to abandon the commercial paper and repo lending markets, some institutions depending on them for funding their operations failed or, later in the crisis, had to be rescued. These markets and other interconnections created contagion, as the crisis spread even to markets and firms that had little or no direct exposure to the mortgage market.

[48] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

For almost a year and a half the global financial system has been under extraordinary stress—stress that has now decisively spilled over to the global economy more broadly. The proximate cause of the crisis was the turn of the housing cycle in the United States and the associated rise in delinquencies on subprime mortgages, which imposed substantial losses on many financial institutions and shook investor confidence in credit markets. However, although the subprime debacle triggered the crisis, the developments in the U.S. mortgage market were only one aspect of a much larger and more encompassing credit boom whose impact transcended the mortgage market to affect many other forms of credit. Aspects of this broader credit boom included widespread declines in underwriting standards, breakdowns in lending oversight by investors and rating agencies, increased reliance on complex and opaque credit instruments that proved fragile under stress, and unusually low compensation for risk-taking.

The abrupt end of the credit boom has had widespread financial and economic ramifications. Financial institutions have seen their capital depleted by losses and writedowns and their balance sheets clogged by complex credit products and other illiquid assets of uncertain value. Rising credit risks and intense risk aversion have pushed credit spreads to unprecedented levels, and markets for securitized assets, except for mortgage securities with government guarantees, have shut down. Heightened systemic risks, falling asset values, and tightening credit have in turn taken a heavy toll on business and consumer confidence and precipitated a sharp slowing in global economic activity. The damage, in terms of lost output, lost jobs, and lost wealth, is already substantial.

[49] Report: “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, September 20, 2010. <www.nber.org>

“Contractions (recessions) start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. … Peak [=] December 2007 (IV) … Trough [=] June 2009 (II)”

[50] Article: “The Great Recession.” By Robert Rich. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The Federal Reserve’s response to the crisis evolved over time and took a number of nontraditional avenues. Initially, the Fed employed “traditional” policy actions by reducing the federal funds rate from 5.25 percent in September 2007 to a range of 0–0.25 percent in December 2008. … The sharp reduction in those periods reflected a marked downgrade in the economic outlook and the increased downside risks to both output and inflation (including the risk of deflation).

[51] Webpage: “How Does Monetary Policy Influence Inflation and Employment?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated December 16, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

During normal times, the Federal Reserve has primarily influenced overall financial conditions by adjusting the federal funds rate—the rate that banks charge each other for short-term loans. Movements in the federal funds rate are passed on to other short-term interest rates that influence borrowing costs for firms and households. Movements in short-term interest rates also influence long-term interest rates—such as corporate bond rates and residential mortgage rates—because those rates reflect, among other factors, the current and expected future values of short-term rates. …

In turn, these changes in financial conditions affect economic activity. For example, when short- and long-term interest rates go down, it becomes cheaper to borrow, so households are more willing to buy goods and services and firms are in a better position to purchase items to expand their businesses, such as property and equipment. …

Monetary policy also has an important influence on inflation. When the federal funds rate is reduced, the resulting stronger demand for goods and services tends to push wages and other costs higher, reflecting the greater demand for workers and materials that are necessary for production.

[52] Article: “Quantitative Easing: How Well Does This Tool Work?” by Stephen D. Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, 2017. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Quantitative easing (QE)—large-scale purchases of assets by central banks—led to a large increase in the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet during the global financial crisis (2007–2008) and in the long recovery from the 2008–2009 recession. … QE consists of large-scale asset purchases by central banks, usually of long-maturity government debt but also of private assets, such as corporate debt or asset-backed securities. Typically, QE occurs in unconventional circumstances, when short-term nominal interest rates are very low, zero or even negative. …

Traditionally, the interest rate that the Fed targets is the federal funds (fed funds) rate. Suppose, though, that the fed funds rate target is zero, but inflation is below the Fed’s 2 percent target and aggregate output is lower than potential. If the effective lower bound were not a binding constraint, the Fed would choose to lower the fed funds rate target, but it cannot. What then? The Fed faced such a situation at the end of 2008, during the financial crisis, and resorted to unconventional monetary policy, including a series of QE experiments that continued into late 2014. …

At the 2010 Jackson Hole conference, then-Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke attempted to articulate the Fed’s rationale for QE. Bernanke’s view was that, with short-term nominal interest rates at zero, purchases by the central bank of long-maturity assets would act to push up the prices of those securities because the Fed was reducing their net supply. Thus, long-maturity bond yields should go down, for example, if the Fed purchases long-maturity Treasury securities.

[53] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Some observers have expressed the concern that, by expanding its balance sheet, the Federal Reserve is effectively printing money, an action that will ultimately be inflationary. The Fed’s lending activities have indeed resulted in a large increase in the excess reserves held by banks. Bank reserves, together with currency, make up the narrowest definition of money, the monetary base; as you would expect, this measure of money has risen significantly as the Fed’s balance sheet has expanded.

[54] Article: “Exiting from Monetary Stimulus: A Better Plan for the Fed.” By Benn Steil. Council on Foreign Relations, Center for Geoeconomic Studies, March 14, 2013. <cfrd8-files.cfr.org>

“In a sustained, extraordinary policy undertaking to counter the enduring economic headwinds of the 2008 financial crisis, the Fed has pumped trillions of dollars of liquidity into the banking system over the past four and a half years. It has accomplished this by buying, with newly conjured dollars, a historically unprecedented amount and variety of securities.”

[56] “95th Annual Report, 2008.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 56:

[T]he Federal Reserve announced on November 25 a program to purchase up to $100 billion in direct obligations of housing-related government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs)…. Purchases of agency debt obligations began in December….

The program to purchase GSE direct obligations has initially focused on fixed-rate, noncallable, senior benchmark securities issued by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks.

[57] Website: “Toxic Assets.” Nasdaq. Accessed August 16, 2018 at <www.nasdaq.com>

Definition:

In the context of the 2007–2009 recession, the term refers to assets like mortgage-backed securities and collateralized debt obligations that are illiquid and difficult to value. If the value of the underlying assets falls significantly, these securities could lose value rapidly (aggravated by the lack of liquidity and transparency in price) which could lead to significant write-downs (and hence losses) for holders of these toxic assets.

[58] “95th Annual Report, 2008.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 55–56: “To help reduce the cost and increase the availability of residential mortgage credit, the Federal Reserve announced on November 25 a program to purchase … up to $500 billion in MBS [mortgage-backed securities] backed by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, the Federal Home Loan Banks, and Ginnie Mae. … [P]urchases of MBS began in January.”

[59] Website: “FAQs: MBS Purchase Program.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, August 20, 2010. <www.newyorkfed.org>

What Was the Volume of MBS Purchased?

The FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] directed the Desk to purchase $1.25 trillion of agency MBS [mortgage-backed securities]. Actual purchases by the program effectively reached this target. The purchase activity began on January 5, 2009 and continued through March 31, 2010.

[60] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 47: “In addition, between March 2009 and October 2009, the Federal Reserve purchased $300 billion of longer-term Treasury securities. Later, in the face of a sluggish economic recovery, the Federal Reserve expanded its asset holdings in a second purchase program between November 2010 and June 2011, buying an additional $600 billion of longer-term Treasury securities.”

Page 53:

Simplified View of the Federal Reserve Balance Sheet, as of January 20, 2016

Assets (millions of dollars)

Treasury securities held outright [=] 2,461,396

[61] Article: “The Great Recession and Its Aftermath.” By John Weinberg. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

“While the U.S. economy bottomed out in the middle of 2009, the recovery in the years immediately following was by some measures unusually slow.”

[62] Calculated with the dataset: “Table 1.1.1 Percent Change From Preceding Period in Real Gross Domestic Product [Percent].” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Last revised May 30, 2018. <www.bea.gov>

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[63] Report: “Virtual Currencies: Key Definitions and Potential AML/CFT Risks.” Financial Action Task Force, June 2014. <www.fatf-gafi.org>

Page 4:

Virtual currency is a digital representation5 of value that can be digitally traded and functions as (1) a medium of exchange; and/or (2) a unit of account; and/or (3) a store of value, but does not have legal tender status (i.e., when tendered to a creditor, is a valid and legal offer of payment)6 in any jurisdiction.7 … [F]iat currency (a.k.a. “real currency, real money,” or “national currency”) … is the coin and paper money of a country that is designated as its legal tender; circulates; and is customarily used and accepted as a medium of exchange in the issuing country. … [E]-money … is a digital representation of fiat currency used to electronically transfer value denominated in fiat currency. E-money is a digital transfer mechanism for fiat currency—i.e., it electronically transfers value that has legal tender status.

Digital currency can mean a digital representation of either virtual currency (non-fiat) or e-money (fiat) and thus is often used interchangeably with the term ‘virtual currency.’

[64] Report: “Virtual Currencies: Key Definitions and Potential AML/CFT Risks.” Financial Action Task Force, June 2014. <www.fatf-gafi.org>

Page 4:

Virtual currency is a digital representation5 of value that can be digitally traded and functions as (1) a medium of exchange; and/or (2) a unit of account; and/or (3) a store of value, but does not have legal tender status (i.e., when tendered to a creditor, is a valid and legal offer of payment)6 in any jurisdiction.7 It is not issued nor guaranteed by any jurisdiction, and fulfills the above functions only by agreement within the community of users of the virtual currency. Virtual currency is distinguished from fiat currency (a.k.a. “real currency,” “real money,” or “national currency”), which is the coin and paper money of a country that is designated as its legal tender; circulates; and is customarily used and accepted as a medium of exchange in the issuing country. …

Convertible (or open) virtual currency has an equivalent value in real currency and can be exchanged back-and-forth for real currency.9 Examples include: Bitcoin; e-Gold (defunct); Liberty Reserve (defunct); Second Life Linden Dollars; and WebMoney.10

Non-convertible (or closed) virtual currency is intended to be specific to a particular virtual domain or world, such as a Massively Multiplayer Online Role-Playing Game (MMORPG) or Amazon.com, and under the rules governing its use, cannot be exchanged for fiat currency. Examples include: Project Entropia Dollars; Q Coins; and World of Warcraft Gold.

[65] Webpage: “Virtual Currencies.” Internal Revenue Service. Last reviewed or updated November 14, 2017. <www.irs.gov>

The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) is aware that “virtual currency” may be used to pay for goods or services, or held for investment. Virtual currency is a digital representation of value that functions as a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and/or a store of value. In some environments, it operates like “real” currency—i.e., the coin and paper money of the United States or of any other country that is designated as legal tender, circulates, and is customarily used and accepted as a medium of exchange in the country of issuance—but it does not have legal tender status in any jurisdiction.

[66] Report: “Virtual Currencies: Key Definitions and Potential AML/CFT Risks.” Financial Action Task Force, June 2014. <www.fatf-gafi.org>

Page 5:

Decentralised Virtual Currencies (a.k.a. crypto-currencies) are distributed13, open-source, math-based peer-to-peer virtual currencies that have no central administrating authority, and no central monitoring or oversight. Examples: Bitcoin; LiteCoin; and Ripple.14

Cryptocurrency refers to a math-based, decentralised convertible virtual currency that is protected by cryptography—i.e., it incorporates principles of cryptography to implement a distributed, decentralised, secure information economy.

[67] Entry: “Bitcoin.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 2012. <www.britannica.com>

“Nakamoto was concerned that traditional currencies were too reliant on the trustworthiness of banks to work properly. Nakamoto proposed a digital currency, Bitcoin, that could serve as a medium of exchange without relying on any financial institutions or governments.”

[68] Speech: “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We Learning?” By Lael Bainard. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 15, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Digital currencies use automation via computer processing power, networking via the internet, and cryptography to transfer value from one person to another. What is innovative is that the computer code behind these transactions uses automated checks and balances to validate the sender and receiver, and whether there is enough value in the sender’s account to make the payment. Traditionally, this validation would be done by banks and payment networks. Instead, with a cryptocurrency, this validation could be done by anyone with enough computing power and resources to participate. Importantly, this technology is not owned or managed by any entity—regulated or not—that would be responsible for its maintenance, security, and reliability.

[69] Article: “Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System.” By Satoshi Nakamoto. Bitcoin. Accessed August 14, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

Page 1:

Commerce on the Internet has come to rely almost exclusively on financial institutions serving as trusted third parties to process electronic payments. While the system works well enough for most transactions, it still suffers from the inherent weaknesses of the trust based model. …

What is needed is an electronic payment system based on cryptographic proof instead of trust, allowing any two willing parties to transact directly with each other without the need for a trusted third party. Transactions that are computationally impractical to reverse would protect sellers from fraud, and routine escrow mechanisms could easily be implemented to protect buyers. In this paper, we propose a solution to the double-spending problem using a peer-to-peer distributed timestamp server to generate computational proof of the chronological order of transactions.

[70] Webpage: “How Does Bitcoin Work?” Bitcoin. Accessed August 15, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

Transactions—Private Keys

A transaction is a transfer of value between Bitcoin wallets that gets included in the block chain. Bitcoin wallets keep a secret piece of data called a private key or seed, which is used to sign transactions, providing a mathematical proof that they have come from the owner of the wallet. The signature also prevents the transaction from being altered by anybody once it has been issued. All transactions are broadcast to the network and usually begin to be confirmed within 10–20 minutes, through a process called mining.

Processing—Mining

Mining is a distributed consensus system that is used to confirm pending transactions by including them in the block chain. It enforces a chronological order in the block chain, protects the neutrality of the network, and allows different computers to agree on the state of the system. To be confirmed, transactions must be packed in a block that fits very strict cryptographic rules that will be verified by the network. These rules prevent previous blocks from being modified because doing so would invalidate all the subsequent blocks.

[71] Speech: “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We Learning?” By Lael Bainard. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 15, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“The past decade has seen a wave of important new developments in digital technologies for payments, clearing, and settlement. Cryptocurrencies represent the leading edge of this digital wave. And it was the advent a decade ago of Bitcoin, the first cryptocurrency, that first gave shape to the vision of a decentralized digital currency.”

[72] Entry: “Bitcoin.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 2012. <www.britannica.com>

“Bitcoin, digital currency created by an anonymous computer programmer or group of programmers known as Satoshi Nakamoto in 2009. Owners of Bitcoins can use various Web sites to trade them for physical currencies, such as U.S. dollars or euros, or can exchange them for goods and services from a number of vendors.”

[73] Webpage: “XRP: The Digital Asset for Payments.” Ripple. Accessed September 4, 2018 at <ripple.com>

“Built for enterprise use, XRP offers banks and payment providers a reliable, on-demand option to source liquidity for cross-border payments. … Established in 2012.”

[74] Paper: “Building Network Effects on Ripple.” Ripple, November 30, 2015. <ripple.com>

Page 6: “Using XRP as a bridge asset, complex cross-currency payments can be executed without additional trading parties, translating to lower costs for even exotic corridors.”

[75] Entry: “Bitcoin.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 2012. <www.britannica.com>

“Transactions are put together in groups called blocks. The blocks are organized in a chronological sequence called the blockchain. Blocks are added to the chain using a mathematical process that makes it extremely difficult for an individual user to hijack the blockchain.”

[76] Webpage: “How Does Bitcoin Work?” Bitcoin. Accessed August 15, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

Balances—Block Chain

The block chain is a shared public ledger on which the entire Bitcoin network relies. All confirmed transactions are included in the block chain. It allows Bitcoin wallets to calculate their spendable balance so that new transactions can be verified thereby ensuring they’re actually owned by the spender. The integrity and the chronological order of the block chain are enforced with cryptography.

[77] Speech: “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We Learning?” By Lael Bainard. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 15, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“For instance, Bitcoin relies on the blockchain, which is run by anonymous computers all over the world linked together through a ledger of anonymized transactions.”

[78] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions.” Bitcoin. Accessed August 15, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

Transparent and neutral—All information concerning the Bitcoin money supply itself is readily available on the block chain for anybody to verify and use in real-time. No individual or organization can control or manipulate the Bitcoin protocol because it is cryptographically secure. This allows the core of Bitcoin to be trusted for being completely neutral, transparent and predictable. …

Much of the trust in Bitcoin comes from the fact that it requires no trust at all. Bitcoin is fully open-source and decentralized. This means that anyone has access to the entire source code at any time. Any developer in the world can therefore verify exactly how Bitcoin works. All transactions and bitcoins issued into existence can be transparently consulted in real-time by anyone. All payments can be made without reliance on a third party and the whole system is protected by heavily peer-reviewed cryptographic algorithms like those used for online banking. No organization or individual can control Bitcoin, and the network remains secure even if not all of its users can be trusted.

[79] Entry: “Bitcoin.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 2012. <www.britannica.com>

So that no Bitcoin can be spent more than once at the same time, the time and amount of each transaction is recorded in a ledger file that exists at each node of the network. The identities of the users remain relatively anonymous, but everyone can see that certain Bitcoins were transferred. … The blockchain technology that underpins Bitcoin has attracted considerable attention, even from skeptics of Bitcoin, as a basis for allowing trustworthy record-keeping and commerce without a central authority.

[80] Speech: “The Use of Distributed Ledger Technologies in Payment, Clearing, and Settlement.” By Lael Brainard. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, April 14, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

In the extreme, distributed ledger technologies are seen as enabling a much larger universe of financial actors to transact directly with other financial actors and to exchange assets versus funds (that is, to “clear” and settle the underlying transactions) virtually instantaneously without the help of intermediaries both within and across borders. This dramatic reduction in frictions would be facilitated by distributed ledgers shared across various networks of financial actors that would keep a complete and accurate record of all transactions, and meet appropriate goals for transparency, privacy, and security.

[81] Webpage: “Top 9 Frequently Asked Questions About Ripple and XRP.” Ripple, January 18, 2018. <ripple.com>

The XRP Ledger is where XRP transactions occur and are recorded. The software that maintains the Ledger is open source and executes continually on a distributed network of servers operated by a variety of organizations. It’s an open-source code base that actively develops and maintains the ledger. …

… While Ripple contributes to the open-source code of the XRP Ledger, we don’t own, control, or administer the XRP Ledger. The XRP Ledger is decentralized. …

All transactions on XRP Ledger are publicly viewable.

[82] Report: “Credit Cards, Rising Interchange Fees Have Increased Costs for Merchants, but Options for Reducing Fees Pose Challenges.” U.S. Government Accountability Office, November 2009. <www.gao.gov>

Page 9:

Acquiring institutions provide the means for merchants to accept credit cards, by forwarding the request for authorization through the card network to the cardholder’s issuing institution. The issuing institution authorizes the transaction by verifying that the account is valid and that the cardholder has a sufficient amount of credit for the sale. For merchants accepting cards in their stores, authorization generally occurs automatically through electronic point-of-sale terminals that read cards. Acquiring institutions clear and settle card purchases by providing payment from the issuing institution to the merchant’s account, except for the interchange fees and their own service fees. According to industry estimates, the process takes between 24 and 72 hours for the merchant to receive payment.

[83] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions.” Bitcoin. Accessed August 26, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

It is possible to send and receive bitcoins anywhere in the world at any time. No bank holidays. No borders. No bureaucracy. Bitcoin allows its users to be in full control of their money. …

Receiving notification of a payment is almost instant with Bitcoin. However, there is a delay before the network begins to confirm your transaction by including it in a block. A confirmation means that there is a consensus on the network that the bitcoins you received haven’t been sent to anyone else and are considered your property. Once your transaction has been included in one block, it will continue to be buried under every block after it, which will exponentially consolidate this consensus and decrease the risk of a reversed transaction. Each confirmation takes between a few seconds and 90 minutes, with 10 minutes being the average.

[84] Webpage: “XRP: The Digital Asset for Payments.” Ripple. Accessed August 26, 2018 at <ripple.com>

“Payments settle in 4 seconds. … XRP consistently handles 1,500 transactions per second, 24x7, and can scale to handle the same throughput as Visa.”

[85] Report: “Virtual Currencies: Key Definitions and Potential AML/CFT Risks.” Financial Action Task Force, June 2014. <www.fatf-gafi.org>

Pages 8–9:

Virtual currency has the potential to improve payment efficiency and reduce transaction costs for payments and fund transfers. For example, Bitcoin functions as a global currency that can avoid exchange fees, is currently processed with lower fees/charges than traditional credit and debit cards, and may potentially provide benefit to existing online payment systems, like Paypal.16 Virtual currency may also facilitate micro-payments, allowing businesses to monetise very low-cost goods or services sold on the Internet, such as onetime game or music downloads. At present, as a practical matter, such items cannot be sold at an appropriately low per/unit cost because of the higher transaction costs associated with e.g., traditional credit and debit.

[86] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions.” Bitcoin. Accessed September 5, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

There is no fee to receive bitcoins, and many wallets let you control how large a fee to pay when spending. Higher fees can encourage faster confirmation of your transactions. Fees are unrelated to the amount transferred, so it’s possible to send 100,000 bitcoins for the same fee it costs to send 1 bitcoin. Additionally, merchant processors exist to assist merchants in processing transactions, converting bitcoins to fiat currency and depositing funds directly into merchants’ bank accounts daily. As these services are based on Bitcoin, they can be offered for much lower fees than with PayPal or credit card networks. …

Transactions can be processed without fees, but trying to send free transactions can require waiting days or weeks. Although fees may increase over time, normal fees currently only cost a tiny amount. By default, all Bitcoin wallets listed on Bitcoin.org add what they think is an appropriate fee to your transactions; most of those wallets will also give you chance to review the fee before sending the transaction.

Transaction fees are used as a protection against users sending transactions to overload the network and as a way to pay miners for their work helping to secure the network. The precise manner in which fees work is still being developed and will change over time. Because the fee is not related to the amount of bitcoins being sent, it may seem extremely low or unfairly high. Instead, the fee is relative to the number of bytes in the transaction, so using multisig or spending multiple previously-received amounts may cost more than simpler transactions. If your activity follows the pattern of conventional transactions, you won't have to pay unusually high fees.

[87] Report: “Credit Cards, Rising Interchange Fees Have Increased Costs for Merchants, but Options for Reducing Fees Pose Challenges.” U.S. Government Accountability Office, November 2009. <www.gao.gov>

Page 18: “[A] recent survey of 750 small business owners found that merchants with fewer than 250 employees paid an average of 3.2 percent to accept American Express Cards and 2.5 percent for Discover cards, compared with the average merchant discount fee (which includes the interchange fee and acquiring costs) that these merchants reported of 2.3 percent for MasterCard and Visa.”

[88] Webpage: “Become an XRP Ledger Gateway.” Ripple. Accessed September 5, 2018 at <developers.ripple.com>

“XRP Ledger payments are irreversible, but many electronic money systems like credit cards or PayPal are not.”

[89] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions.” Bitcoin. Accessed August 31, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

Bitcoin transactions are secure, irreversible, and do not contain customers’ sensitive or personal information. This protects merchants from losses caused by fraud or fraudulent chargebacks….

Mining creates the equivalent of a competitive lottery that makes it very difficult for anyone to consecutively add new blocks of transactions into the block chain. … This also prevents any individual from replacing parts of the block chain to roll back their own spends, which could be used to defraud other users. Mining makes it exponentially more difficult to reverse a past transaction by requiring the rewriting of all blocks following this transaction.

[90] Speech: “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We Learning?” By Lael Bainard. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 15, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“And while a typical cryptocurrency may be used in payments, it is not legal tender, in contrast to U.S. currency.”

[91] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions.” Bitcoin. Accessed August 15, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

Why Do Bitcoins Have Value?

Bitcoins have value because they are useful as a form of money. Bitcoin has the characteristics of money (durability, portability, fungibility, scarcity, divisibility, and recognizability) based on the properties of mathematics rather than relying on physical properties (like gold and silver) or trust in central authorities (like fiat currencies). In short, Bitcoin is backed by mathematics. With these attributes, all that is required for a form of money to hold value is trust and adoption. In the case of Bitcoin, this can be measured by its growing base of users, merchants, and startups. As with all currency, bitcoin’s value comes only and directly from people willing to accept them as payment.

[92] Article: “Cryptocurrency.” By James Surowiecki. MIT Technology Review, August 23, 2011. <www.technologyreview.com>

“Tens of thousands of bitcoins are traded each day (some for goods and services, others in exchange for other currencies), and several hundred businesses, mostly in the digital world, now take bitcoins as payment.”

[93] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions.” Bitcoin. Accessed August 26, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

The price of a bitcoin is determined by supply and demand. When demand for bitcoins increases, the price increases, and when demand falls, the price falls. There is only a limited number of bitcoins in circulation and new bitcoins are created at a predictable and decreasing rate, which means that demand must follow this level of inflation to keep the price stable. Because Bitcoin is still a relatively small market compared to what it could be, it doesn't take significant amounts of money to move the market price up or down, and thus the price of a bitcoin is still very volatile.

[94] Webpage: “Some Things You Need to Know.” Bitcoin. Accessed August 15, 2018 at <bitcoin.org>

Bitcoin Price Is Volatile

The price of a bitcoin can unpredictably increase or decrease over a short period of time due to its young economy, novel nature, and sometimes illiquid markets. Consequently, keeping your savings with Bitcoin is not recommended at this point. Bitcoin should be seen like a high risk asset, and you should never store money that you cannot afford to lose with Bitcoin. If you receive payments with Bitcoin, many service providers can convert them to your local currency.

[95] Speech: “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We Learning?” By Lael Bainard. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 15, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“But there are also serious challenges. For instance, cryptocurrencies have exhibited periods of extreme volatility. If you purchased Bitcoin in December 2017 at a value of over $19,000, your electronic claims would be worth close to half that today. Indeed, Bitcoin’s value has been known to fluctuate by one-quarter in one day alone.”

[96] Webpage: “Board Members.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated January 11, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Lael Brainard took office as a member of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System on June 16, 2014, to fill an unexpired term ending January 31, 2026.”

[97] Speech: “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We Learning?” By Lael Bainard. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 15, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

This combination of a new asset, which is not a liability of any individual or institution, and a new recordkeeping and transfer technology, which is not maintained by any single individual or institution, illustrates the powerful capabilities of today’s technologies. But there are also serious challenges. For instance, cryptocurrencies have exhibited periods of extreme volatility. If you purchased Bitcoin in December 2017 at a value of over $19,000, your electronic claims would be worth close to half that today. Indeed, Bitcoin’s value has been known to fluctuate by one-quarter in one day alone. Such extreme fluctuations limit an asset’s ability to fulfill two of the classic functions of money: to act as a stable store of value that people can hold and use predictably in the future, and to serve as a meaningful unit of account that can be used to assign a comparable value of goods and services.

[98] Entry: “Inflation.” By David Ranson. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

“Inflation is the loss in purchasing power of a currency unit such as the dollar, usually expressed as a general rise in the prices of goods and services.”

[99] Article: “Inflation: Prices on the Rise.” By Ceyda Oner. International Monetary Fund. Updated July 29, 2017. <www.imf.org>

Inflation is the rate of increase in prices over a given period of time. Inflation is typically a broad measure, such as the overall increase in prices or the increase in the cost of living in a country. But it can also be more narrowly calculated—for example, for certain goods, such as food, or for services, such as school tuition. Whatever the context, inflation represents how much more expensive the relevant set of goods and/or services has become over a certain period, most commonly a year.

[100] Speech: “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here.” By Ben S. Bernanke. The Federal Reserve Board, November 21, 2002. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Since World War II, inflation—the apparently inexorable rise in the prices of goods and services—has been the bane of central bankers.”

[101] Textbook: Macroeconomics (6th edition). By N. Gregory Mankiw. Worth Publishers, 2007.

Page 103: “Hyperinflation is often defined as inflation that exceeds 50 percent per month, which is just over 1 percent per day.”

[102] Article: “Inflation: Prices on the Rise.” By Ceyda Oner. International Monetary Fund. Updated July 29, 2017. <www.imf.org>

“Long-lasting episodes of high inflation are often the result of lax monetary policy. If the money supply grows too big relative to the size of an economy, the unit value of the currency diminishes; in other words, its purchasing power falls and prices rise.”

[103] Speech: “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here.” By Ben S. Bernanke. The Federal Reserve Board, November 21, 2002. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Like gold, U.S. dollars have value only to the extent that they are strictly limited in supply. But the U.S. government has a technology, called a printing press (or, today, its electronic equivalent), that allows it to produce as many U.S. dollars as it wishes at essentially no cost. By increasing the number of U.S. dollars in circulation, or even by credibly threatening to do so, the U.S. government can also reduce the value of a dollar in terms of goods and services, which is equivalent to raising the prices in dollars of those goods and services. We conclude that, under a paper-money system, a determined government can always generate higher spending and hence positive inflation.

Of course, the U.S. government is not going to print money and distribute it willy-nilly (although as we will see later, there are practical policies that approximate this behavior).

[104] Article: “Inflation: Prices on the Rise.” By Ceyda Oner. International Monetary Fund. Updated July 29, 2017. <www.imf.org>

Pressures on the supply or demand side of the economy can also be inflationary. Supply shocks that disrupt production, such as natural disasters, or raise production costs, such as high oil prices, can reduce overall supply and lead to “cost-push” inflation, in which the impetus for price increases comes from a disruption to supply. The food and fuel inflation episodes of 2008 and 2011 were such cases for the global economy—sharply rising food and fuel prices were transmitted from country to country by trade…. Conversely, demand shocks, such as a stock market rally, or expansionary policies, such as when a central bank lowers interest rates or a government raises spending, can temporarily boost overall demand and economic growth. If, however, this increase in demand exceeds an economy’s production capacity, the resulting strain on resources creates “demand-pull” inflation. Policymakers must find the right balance between boosting growth when needed without overstimulating the economy and causing inflation.

[105] Article: “Understanding Deflation.” By Tao Wu. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letters, April 2, 2004. <www.frbsf.org>

“Deflation refers not to falling prices anywhere in the economy, but to a decline in the general price level across the economy.”

[106] Book: Deflation: Current and Historical Perspectives. Edited by Richard C. K. Burdekin and Pierre L. Siklos. Cambridge University Press, 2004.

Page 6:

[I]t is still true that sustained deflation is only possible when the rate of money growth falls behind the rate of growth of output and money demand. Just as the inflation of the 1970s could not be ascribed to supply shocks alone, but rather required central bank accommodation of these supply shocks through loose monetary policy, sustained deflation must surely imply a similar failure of central bank policy in the opposite direction.

[107] Article: “U.S. Historical Experience with Deflation.” By Christopher J. Neely. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses, October 19, 2010. <files.stlouisfed.org>

“What causes deflation? Central banks can influence the money supply to determine the average inflation rate over a long period….”

[108] Article: “U.S. Historical Experience with Deflation.” By Christopher J. Neely. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses, October 19, 2010. <files.stlouisfed.org>

“What causes deflation? Central banks can influence the money supply to determine the average inflation rate over a long period….”

[109] Speech: “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here.” By Ben S. Bernanke. The Federal Reserve Board, November 21, 2002. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Deflation per se occurs only when price declines are so widespread that broad-based indexes of prices, such as the consumer price index, register ongoing declines.

The sources of deflation are not a mystery. Deflation is in almost all cases a side effect of a collapse of aggregate demand—a drop in spending so severe that producers must cut prices on an ongoing basis in order to find buyers.1 Likewise, the economic effects of a deflationary episode, for the most part, are similar to those of any other sharp decline in aggregate spending—namely, recession, rising unemployment, and financial stress.

1 Conceivably, deflation could also be caused by a sudden, large expansion in aggregate supply arising, for example, from rapid gains in productivity and broadly declining costs. I don’t know of any unambiguous example of a supply-side deflation, although China in recent years is a possible case. Note that a supply-side deflation would be associated with an economic boom rather than a recession.

[110] Article: “U.S. Historical Experience with Deflation.” By Christopher J. Neely. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses, October 19, 2010. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Many people associate deflation with difficult economic times—slow growth and/or high unemployment—such as in Japan since the early 1990s or in the United States during the Great Depression. …

What causes deflation? Central banks can influence the money supply to determine the average inflation rate over a long period, but other factors can affect the inflation rate over shorter periods. These include technological improvements that reduce production costs and/or changes in demand for cash and other safe assets, perhaps associated with a financial crisis.

[111] Speech: “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here.” By Ben S. Bernanke. The Federal Reserve Board, November 21, 2002. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Deflation per se occurs only when price declines are so widespread that broad-based indexes of prices, such as the consumer price index, register ongoing declines.

The sources of deflation are not a mystery. Deflation is in almost all cases a side effect of a collapse of aggregate demand—a drop in spending so severe that producers must cut prices on an ongoing basis in order to find buyers.1

1 Conceivably, deflation could also be caused by a sudden, large expansion in aggregate supply arising, for example, from rapid gains in productivity and broadly declining costs. I don’t know of any unambiguous example of a supply-side deflation, although China in recent years is a possible case. Note that a supply-side deflation would be associated with an economic boom rather than a recession.

[112] Article: “U.S. Historical Experience with Deflation.” By Christopher J. Neely. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses, October 19, 2010. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Many people associate deflation with difficult economic times—slow growth and/or high unemployment—such as in Japan since the early 1990s or in the United States during the Great Depression. …

What causes deflation? Central banks can influence the money supply to determine the average inflation rate over a long period, but other factors can affect the inflation rate over shorter periods. These include technological improvements that reduce production costs and/or changes in demand for cash and other safe assets, perhaps associated with a financial crisis.

[113] Webpage: “What Is Inflation and How Does the Federal Reserve Evaluate Changes in the Rate of Inflation?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Last updated September 9, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Inflation occurs when the prices of goods and services increase over time. Inflation cannot be measured by an increase in the cost of one product or service, or even several products or services. Rather, inflation is a general increase in the overall price level of the goods and services in the economy. Federal Reserve policymakers evaluate changes in inflation by monitoring several different price indexes. A price index measures changes in the price of a group of goods and services.

[114] Webpage: “What Is Inflation and How Does the Federal Reserve Evaluate Changes in the Rate of Inflation?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Last updated September 9, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Fed often emphasizes the price inflation measure for personal consumption expenditures (PCE), produced by the Department of Commerce, largely because the PCE index covers a wide range of household spending. However, the Fed closely tracks other inflation measures as well, including the consumer price indexes and producer price indexes issued by the Department of Labor.

[115] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions (FAQs).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Last modified July 6, 2016. <www.bls.gov>

The CPI affects nearly all Americans because of the many ways it is used. …

As an economic indicator: The CPI is the most widely used measure of inflation and is sometimes viewed as an indicator of the effectiveness of government economic policy. It provides information about price changes in the nation's economy to government, business, labor, and other private citizens, and is used by them as a guide to making economic decisions. In addition, the President, Congress, and the Federal Reserve Board use trends in the CPI to aid in formulating fiscal and monetary policies.

As a means of adjusting dollar values: The CPI is often used to adjust consumers’ income payments (for example, Social Security); to adjust income eligibility levels for government assistance; and to automatically provide cost-of-living wage adjustments to millions of American workers. The CPI affects the income of about 80 million persons as a result of statutory action: 48.4 million Social Security beneficiaries, about 19.8 million food stamp recipients, and about 4.2 million military and federal Civil Service retirees and survivors. Changes in the CPI also affect the cost of lunches for 26.5 million children who eat lunch at school, while collective bargaining agreements that tie wages to the CPI cover over 2 million workers. Another example of how dollar values may be adjusted is the use of the CPI to adjust the federal income tax structure. These adjustments prevent inflation-induced increases in tax rates, an effect called “bracket creep.”

[116] Article: “Differences Between the Consumer Price Index and the Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics Beyond the Numbers, May 1, 2011. <www.bls.gov>

Page 1:

Weight effect. The relative weights assigned to each of the CPI and PCE categories of items are based on different data sources. The relative weights used in the CPI are based primarily on the Consumer Expenditure Survey, a household survey conducted for the BLS by the Census Bureau. The relative weights used in the PCE index are derived from business surveys—for example, the Census Bureau’s annual and monthly retail trade surveys, the Service Annual Survey, and the Quarterly Services Survey.

[117] Article: “PCE and CPI Inflation: What’s the Difference?” By Joseph G. Haubrich and Sara Millington. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Trends, April 17, 2014. <www.clevelandfed.org>

The two measures, though following broadly similar trends, are certainly not identical. In general, the CPI tends to report somewhat higher inflation. …

The first difference is sometimes called the weight effect. In calculating an index number, which is a sort of average, some prices get a heavier weight than others. People spend more on some items than others, so they are a larger part of the basket and thus get more weight in the index. For example, spending is affected more if the price of gasoline rises than if the price of limes goes up. The two indexes have different estimates of the appropriate basket. The CPI is based on a survey of what households are buying; the PCE is based on surveys of what businesses are selling. …

The largest difference tends to be the weight effect, which contributes to bigger changes in the CPI, while the scope effect tends to lessen the difference.

[118] Article: “Differences Between the Consumer Price Index and the Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics Beyond the Numbers, May 1, 2011. <www.bls.gov>

Page 2:

Scope effects. The CPI measures the change in the out-of-pocket expenditures of all urban households and the PCE index measures the change in goods and services consumed by all households, and nonprofit institutions serving households. This conceptual difference means that some items and expenditures in the PCE index are outside the scope of the CPI. For example, the expenditure weights for medical care services in the CPI are derived only from out-of-pocket expenses paid for by consumers. By contrast, medical care services in the PCE index include those services purchased out of pocket by consumers and those services paid for on behalf of consumers—for example, medical care services paid for by employers through employer-provided health insurance, as well as medical care services paid for by governments through programs such as Medicare and Medicaid. These differences can also be isolated and measured, and can be referred to as “scope effects.”

[119] Article: “PCE and CPI Inflation: What’s the Difference?” By Joseph G. Haubrich and Sara Millington. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Trends, April 17, 2014. <www.clevelandfed.org>

The two measures, though following broadly similar trends, are certainly not identical. In general, the CPI tends to report somewhat higher inflation. …

Another aspect of the baskets that leads to differences is referred to as coverage or scope. The CPI only covers out-of-pocket expenditures on goods and services purchased. It excludes other expenditures that are not paid for directly, for example, medical care paid for by employer-provided insurance, Medicare, and Medicaid. These are, however, included in the PCE. …

The largest difference tends to be the weight effect, which contributes to bigger changes in the CPI, while the scope effect tends to lessen the difference.

[120] Article: “Differences Between the Consumer Price Index and the Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics Beyond the Numbers, May 1, 2011. <www.bls.gov>

Page 1:

Formula effect. The CPI and the PCE index are constructed from different index-number formulas. The CPI index is an average based on a Laspeyres formula, whereas the PCE index is based on a Fisher-Ideal formula. A Fisher-Ideal index is considered a “superlative” index in that it reflects consumer substitution among detailed items as relative prices change. In practice, superlative indexes are difficult to implement in real time because such indexes require expenditure data for the period that is current, and such data are not available. For example, data on household consumer expenditures that are used to estimate the CPI are not available for the current period.

[121] Article: “PCE and CPI Inflation: What’s the Difference?” By Joseph G. Haubrich and Sara Millington. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Trends, April 17, 2014. <www.clevelandfed.org>

The two measures, though following broadly similar trends, are certainly not identical. In general, the CPI tends to report somewhat higher inflation. …

Finally, the indexes differ in how they account for changes in the basket. This is referred to as the formula effect, because the indexes themselves are calculated using different formulae.

[122] Calculated with data from:

a) Dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

b) Dataset: “Table 2.3.4. Price Indexes for Personal Consumption Expenditures by Major Type of Product.” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Last revised January 26, 2018. <www.bea.gov>

Line 1: “Personal consumption expenditures (PCE)”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[123] Calculated with data from:

a) Dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

b) Dataset: “Table 2.3.4. Price Indexes for Personal Consumption Expenditures by Major Type of Product.” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Last revised January 26, 2018. <www.bea.gov>

Line 1: “Personal consumption expenditures (PCE)”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[124] Article: “Public Comment on Inflation Measurement and the Chained-CPI.” By John Williams. Shadow Government Statistics, April 8, 2013. <www.shadowstats.com>

Maintaining Constant Standard of Living (Fixed-Basket Inflation) Versus Substitution in CPI

• Since the 1700s, consumer inflation has been estimated by measuring price changes in a fixed-weight basket of goods, effectively measuring the cost of living of maintaining a constant standard of living.

• Allowing substitution of lower-priced and lower-quality goods in the basket (i.e. more hamburger when steak prices rise) lowers the reported rate of inflation versus the fixed-basket measure.

[125] Commentary: “If You Want To Know The Real Rate Of Inflation, Don’t Bother With The CPI.” By Perianne Boring. Forbes, February 3, 2014. <www.forbes.com>

Common sense tells us the Consumer Price Index is not an adequate measure of inflation. For the second year in a row the Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers (CPI-U) remained under 2 percent. On average, consumer prices increased 1.5 percent, according to the government. However, the government has incentives to keep this statistic as low as possible. …

… [T]he government makes the assumption that consumer spending habits change as economic conditions change, including rising prices. So if prices rise and consumers substitute products, the CPI formula could hold a bias that doesn’t report rising prices. Not a very accurate way to measure inflation.

[126] Article: “Public Comment on Inflation Measurement and the Chained-CPI.” By John Williams. Shadow Government Statistics, April 8, 2013. <www.shadowstats.com>

Homeowners’ Equivalent Rent, or Hedonic Adjustments to Imaginary Numbers. On the weighting front, it is worth considering that fully 24.0% of the total current CPI-U inflation reporting reflects the category of “homeowners’ equivalent rent of residences.” Instead of reflecting some measure of home prices, as was the case before 1983, the BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics] estimates the cost of housing based on what homeowners theoretically would pay to themselves in order to rent their own homes from themselves. The BLS then estimates how much homeowners raise the rent on themselves each month. Starting in 1989, the BLS “improved” these estimates by beginning to adjust that imaginary series for hedonic quality adjustments.

[127] Article: “Inflation Bite Worse Than CPI Mark.” Economic Cycle Research Institute, May 16, 2004. <www.businesscycle.com>

Because of a statistical quirk, the CPI has actually undercounted inflation in the recent past and may overcount it in the near future.

Housing Price a Factor

The reason has to do with the price of housing, which composes more than 40 percent of the index. The CPI uses a complex rental equivalent formula that does not reflect the actual rise and fall in U.S. home prices. During the economic slowdown of recent years, low interest rates allowed more people to buy rather than rent. Fewer people were in the rental market, so rents dropped.

“Now, as interest rates rise, that downward pressure will be gone, rents will recover, and that’s what will move the CPI up,” Achuthan said.

[128] Commentary: “Response to BLS Article on CPI Misconceptions.” By John Williams. Shadow Government Statistics, September 10, 2008. <www.shadowstats.com>

“Quality adjustments of the hedonic, more-theoretical kind, however, have tended to reduce reported inflation meaningfully. … Since 1980, the aggregate change in annual CPI inflation reporting due to methodological shifts has been a reduction of roughly 700 basis points (7%).”

[129] Commentary: “The Fake World: Fake Growth, Fake Money, Fake Jobs, Fake Stability, Fake Inflation Numbers.” By Paul Singer. Infowars, November 4, 2014. <www.infowars.com>

[A]ll of the reported growth numbers are too high, because the official inflation number is too low. Over a long period of time, these figures have become politicized, always in the direction of under-reporting inflation. Constant repetition has resulted in most policymakers and economists now just accepting the adjustments and tricks that have become part of the reporting culture. From … ignoring house prices and using “rental equivalence”; to “hedonic adjustments” according to which, if your computer is “better” than last year’s, then you should subtract an amount from the actual price every year to reflect that improvement, even though it is subjective and not really quantifiable; to a handful of other nonsensical adjustments, inflation is understated.

[130] Article: “Addressing Misconceptions About the Consumer Price Index.” By John S. Greenlees and Robert B. McClelland. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, August 2008. <www.bls.gov>

Pages 7–9:

The BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics] has been faced with two types of criticisms, one general and one specific, of the way in which quality adjustment is carried out in the CPI. The first criticism argues, explicitly or implicitly, that no adjustment should be made for the difference in quality between an item that is no longer sold and its replacement. … The second criticism is that, by expanding the use of hedonic quality adjustment over the past 10 years, the BLS has imposed arbitrary estimates of the “pleasure” consumers derive from new products, severely distorting the CPI as a result.

[131] Webpage: “John Williams’ Shadow Government Statistics.” Shadow Government Statistics. Accessed July 23, 2018 at <www.shadowstats.com>

“An old friend … asked me some years back to write a series of articles on the quality of government statistics. The response to those writings … was so strong that we started ShadowStats.com (Shadow Government Statistics) in 2004. The newsletter is published as part of my economic consulting services.”

[132] Article: “Public Comment on Inflation Measurement and the Chained-CPI.” By John Williams. Shadow Government Statistics, April 8, 2013. <www.shadowstats.com>

The substitution-related alterations to inflation methodologies were made beginning in the mid-1990s. The introduction of major hedonic concepts began in the 1980s. The aggregate impact of the reporting changes since 1980 has been to reduce the reported level of annual CPI inflation by roughly seven percentage points, where 5.1 percentage points come from the BLS’s [Bureau of Labor Statistics’] published estimates of the effects of the individual methodological changes on inflation, shown in the preceding table. The balance comes from ShadowStats estimates of the changes not formally estimated by the BLS. The effects are cumulative going forward in time.

[133] Article: “Addressing Misconceptions About the Consumer Price Index.” By John S. Greenlees and Robert B. McClelland. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, August 2008. <www.bls.gov>

Pages 5–7:

Among all the criticisms leveled at the CPI, its use of the geometric mean formula to reflect consumer substitution behavior is undoubtedly the most frequently misunderstood and mischaracterized. …

To begin, it must be stated unequivocally that the BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics] does not assume that consumers substitute hamburger for steak. Neither the CPI-U, nor the CPI-W used for wage and benefit indexation, allows for substitution between steak and hamburger, which are in different CPI item categories.12 Instead, the BLS uses a formula that implicitly assumes a degree of substitution among the close substitutes within an item-area component of the index. As an example, consumers are assumed to respond to price variations among the different items found within the category “apples in Chicago.” Other examples are “ground beef in Chicago,” “beefsteaks in Chicago,” and “eggs in Boston.”

There can be no doubt that consumers exhibit shifts in their purchasing patterns toward items that have fallen in relative price. This behavior is an observable feature of everyday life, not just a theoretical economic principle. Consider a carton of orange juice, which is a typical product found within the CPI item category “nonfrozen noncarbonated juices and drinks.” Suppose that a store lowers the price of one brand of orange juice, while leaving all other prices the same. In response, some consumers will consume more orange juice; some will buy the affected brand of orange juice rather than other brands; some will buy orange juice at this store rather than other stores; some will purchase orange juice instead of grapefruit juice; and some will buy orange juice now rather than later, using the opportunity to stock their refrigerators with a larger-than-usual supply of orange juice. There will be some consumers who do not increase their consumption of that particular brand of orange juice, but almost certainly, the aggregate purchases by all consumers will rise.14

There is also no dispute among economists that the price index formula used in all of the basic CPIs prior to 1999 (called the Laspeyres formula) tends to overstate changes in the cost of living; specifically, the change in a Laspeyres index is an “upper bound” on the change in the cost of maintaining a standard of living.15 This fundamental result is found throughout books on cost-of-living indexes, as well as in economics textbooks.16 It long predates the BLS decision to switch to a geometric mean formula for computing most of the basic CPIs.17

A simple, if extreme, example suffices to get the point across. Suppose that a person buys four candy bars each week: two chocolate bars and two peanut bars. The bars cost $1 each, so her total spending per week on candy bars is $4. Now suppose that, for some reason, the price of chocolate bars quadruples to $4, while peanut bars remain at $1. The goal of the CPI is to measure how much the consumer needs to spend each week to consider herself just as well off as she was before the price increase. A Laspeyres price index calculates the cost of the original purchase quantities: two candy bars of each type. Therefore, the answer according to the Laspeyres formula is that the consumer would need $10 to be as well off as before.18

The Laspeyres answer is correct, however, only if the consumer is completely unconcerned with changes in price and always chooses to purchase chocolate and peanut bars in equal numbers, regardless of which is cheaper. The Laspeyres answer is called an upper bound because the right answer cannot be greater than $10; the consumer certainly will be at least as well off as she was before if she can continue to purchase two bars of each type. At the other extreme, the right answer cannot be lower than $4. In the unlikely case that the consumer is entirely indifferent between types of candy bar, she could respond to the increase in the price of chocolate bars by buying four peanut bars instead of two of each type, and she would be no worse off than she was before, even if she still had only $4 to spend. Of course, neither the Laspeyres upper-bound answer of $10 nor the lower-bound answer of $4 is realistic. In the real world, people make tradeoffs on the basis of both price and their preferences, and the actual answer lies in between the two bounds. With $7, for example, our consumer could afford to buy seven peanut bars, one for every day of the week. Thus, $7 might be sufficient to make her as satisfied at the new prices of candy as she was with $4 at the old prices. Put another way, we can be confident that, for some consumers, the Laspeyres result of $10 would overstate the amount they need to maintain their original level of candy satisfaction. The geometric mean formula adopted by the BLS for use in most CPIs gives a somewhat lower answer than the Laspeyres formula, because it puts less weight on the prices that have increased the most (in this case, the price of chocolate bars) and more weight on the prices that have increased less. As it turns out, the geometric mean would say that $8 is the amount needed to keep the average consumer at the original satisfaction level. With $8, the consumer could purchase one chocolate bar and four peanut bars, offsetting the reduced number of chocolate bars by an increase in the total number of candy bars.19

… [T]he objective is to calculate the amount of money necessary to maintain a constant level of satisfaction, or what one might term a constant standard of living. Critics of the BLS often erroneously assert that reflecting substitution behavior in the CPI amounts to tracking a declining standard of living. Their argument can be summarized as follows: “the BLS assumes that if steak becomes too expensive, consumers will shift to buying hamburger, so the CPI reflects a tradeoff of hamburger for steak, not steak for steak.” The trouble is that that logic fails to recognize the point made at the beginning of this section: that the BLS employs the geometric mean formula only within basic CPIs, such as the index for ground beef in Chicago. Still, despite the fact that it is wrong, the idea that the CPI’s use of the geometric mean reflects substitution between hamburger and steak has attained the status of a sort of urban legend, repeated by numerous bloggers and commentators.

When the price of a certain type of beefsteak rises, CPI-U and CPI-W methods allow only for substitution to other types of beefsteak, not to hamburger or other, cheaper alternatives to steak. A 1998 article in the Monthly Labor Review emphasizes, “the geometric mean formula will not be used to combine the basic indexes in the CPI, such as those for ice cream products and apples, into the overall index.”20 As mentioned earlier, those indexes are combined into the overall CPI-U or CPI-W under the assumption that there is no substitution between ice cream products and apples or between steak and hamburger.

[134] Article: “Addressing Misconceptions About the Consumer Price Index.” By John S. Greenlees and Robert B. McClelland. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, August 2008. <www.bls.gov>

Page 15: “The introduction of the geometric mean formula to account for product substitution has decreased the rate of change of the CPI by less than 0.3 percentage point annually, not by 3 percentage points annually as some have claimed.”

[135] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions (FAQs).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Last modified April 13, 2018. <www.bls.gov>

“The CPI also does not include investment items, such as stocks, bonds, real estate, and life insurance because these items relate to savings, and not to day-to-day consumption expenses.”

[136] Article: “Addressing Misconceptions About the Consumer Price Index.” By John S. Greenlees and Robert B. McClelland. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, August 2008. <www.bls.gov>

Pages 10–11:

In 1983, the BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics] shifted the treatment of homeownership in the CPI-U to rental equivalence. The rental equivalence method is grounded in economic theory, receives broad support from academic economists, and is the most widely used method among the member nations of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).37 The U.N. System of National Accounts 1993 guidelines recommend using the method for measuring household consumption, and it is also used in constructing international comparisons of living standards.38

The CPI for owners’ equivalent rent of primary residence (OER) is based on estimating the market rents for owner-occupied housing units.39 The cost of homeownership is treated as what economists call an opportunity cost: the amount owner-occupants would receive if they did not consume the services of their homes, but instead rented the homes out. In essence, the BLS measures the value of shelter as the amount of money people give up by using it. For renters, that means the amount they pay for renting the home. For homeowners, it means the amount they lose by not renting out their house. …

Using house prices instead of rents to measure homeowner cost is known as the asset, or acquisitions, approach.40 Such an approach has some intuitive appeal and is similar to the treatment of any other CPI commodity. Its long-recognized flaw, however, is that owner-occupied housing combines both consumption and investment elements…. As has routinely been noted by magazine writers, creators of television commercials, and investment advisers, a house is frequently a family’s major investment. The CPI is designed to exclude investment items, and real estate is one of these exclusions, along with stocks, bonds, and whole-life insurance. The logic behind excluding house prices from the CPI is suggested by the fact that homeowners are often pleased when the price of their housing assets increases, as they are when stock prices rise, whereas consumers are seldom pleased when the prices of food, energy, or other consumer goods rise. Currently, the squeeze many homeowners feel as home values decline while the prices of food and gasoline rise is evidence that simply inserting home prices in the CPI-U—which would lower the estimated rate of inflation—would be inappropriate. …

The 1996 “Boskin Commission” supported the rental equivalence approach to homeownership, even arguing that the CPI treatment of owner-occupied housing should be extended to automobiles and all other durable goods.43 More recently, the 2002 report of the National Research Council panel states, “for long-lived items like automobiles or houses … one must use not the purchase price but the consumption price” and “as is the current practice with housing, we believe that using rental rates is probably the best option.”44

37 The OECD, which is composed mainly of industrialized, developed countries, recently reported that 13 of its 30 members use rental equivalence in their national CPIs. The next-most-frequent alternative is simply leaving owner-occupied housing out of the index (8 countries). …

[137] Article: “Addressing Misconceptions About the Consumer Price Index.” By John S. Greenlees and Robert B. McClelland. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, August 2008. <www.bls.gov>

Pages 7–10:

The BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics] has been faced with two types of criticisms, one general and one specific, of the way in which quality adjustment is carried out in the CPI. The first criticism argues, explicitly or implicitly, that no adjustment should be made for the difference in quality between an item that is no longer sold and its replacement. That position appears to be based on a misunderstanding of the purpose of the CPI, and it also is impractical, given the rapidly changing consumer marketplace. The second criticism is that, by expanding the use of hedonic quality adjustment over the past 10 years, the BLS has imposed arbitrary estimates of the “pleasure” consumers derive from new products, severely distorting the CPI as a result. This criticism is a fundamental misunderstanding of the hedonic method, and it ignores the fact that the introduction of all hedonic quality adjustments since 1999 has had only a very small impact on the overall CPI. …

Why does the BLS adjust for quality change at all? Many of the challenges associated with producing a CPI arise because the number and types of goods and services found in the market are constantly changing. Over time, the goods and services in the CPI samples are being replaced by new products or by new models of existing products. Consequently, if the BLS tried to maintain a fixed and unchanging sample for the CPI, that sample would quickly shrink to the point where it became unrepresentative of what consumers were purchasing. Each time an item in the CPI sample permanently disappears from the shelves, the BLS has to choose another item and then has to make some determination about the relative qualities of the old and replacement items. If it tried to avoid making such quality determinations and adjustments—for example, if it treated all new items as identical to those they replaced—significant upward or downward CPI biases would result. As stated in the international CPI manual published by the International Labor Office (ILO), “Statistical offices must pay close attention to the treatment of quality change and try to make explicit adjustments whenever possible.”27

Moreover, quality adjustment, whether based on hedonic methods or not, adjusts prices between the old and new good only to the degree that they differ in quality. Contrary to what some have claimed, it does not amount to “zeroing out” a price change because quality increased. When prices are adjusted for quality, there is no reason to believe that the price change has been eliminated, and the quality-adjusted price change can be either less than or greater than the unadjusted price change, depending on whether quality increased or decreased. …

It is also important to emphasize that the BLS makes hedonic adjustments for declines, as well as improvements, in quality. The CPI price indexes for shelter include hedonic adjustments for the gradual aging of the rental housing units in the CPI sample, and those adjustments regularly increase the rate of change of the indexes by at least 0.2 percentage point per year.32 The hedonic adjustments in apparel have had both upward and downward impacts at different points in time and for different categories of clothing.33 As discussed in an article in the Monthly Labor Review,34 the BLS estimates that the hedonic quality adjustments introduced since 1998 have had an upward impact in five item categories and a downward impact in five. The overall impact of these newly introduced hedonic models has been quite modest and in an upward, not downward, direction. To be precise, the use of the models has increased the annual rate of change of the all-items CPI, but by only about 0.005 percent per year.35 It is clear, therefore, that those who maintain that the BLS uses hedonic adjustment to keep the measured rate of inflation in an acceptably low range are wrong about the impacts, as well as the motives, of BLS actions. …

So long as new products are successful because they offer improvements that are valued by most consumers, it would be inappropriate for BLS simply to ignore those improvements. Some might argue, for example, that when an inexpensive black-and-white television disappears from the market, the CPI should treat the full difference between its price and the price of a color television as a price increase. This approach would be no more reasonable, however, than incorporating a large price decrease into the CPI when the Concorde supersonic transport stopped flying and consumers were forced to switch to slower transatlantic flights.

[138] Article: “Addressing Misconceptions About the Consumer Price Index.” By John S. Greenlees and Robert B. McClelland. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, August 2008. <www.bls.gov>

Page 9:

It is also important to emphasize that the BLS makes hedonic adjustments for declines, as well as improvements, in quality. The CPI price indexes for shelter include hedonic adjustments for the gradual aging of the rental housing units in the CPI sample, and those adjustments regularly increase the rate of change of the indexes by at least 0.2 percentage point per year.32 The hedonic adjustments in apparel have had both upward and downward impacts at different points in time and for different categories of clothing.33 As discussed in an article in the Monthly Labor Review,34 the BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics] estimates that the hedonic quality adjustments introduced since 1998 have had an upward impact in five item categories and a downward impact in five. The overall impact of these newly introduced hedonic models has been quite modest and in an upward, not downward, direction. To be precise, the use of the models has increased the annual rate of change of the all-items CPI, but by only about 0.005 percent per year.35 It is clear, therefore, that those who maintain that the BLS uses hedonic adjustment to keep the measured rate of inflation in an acceptably low range are wrong about the impacts, as well as the motives, of BLS actions.

Page 15: “Hedonic quality adjustments introduced in the last 10 years have had a very small impact on the all-items CPI.”

[139] Article: “Addressing Misconceptions About the Consumer Price Index.” By John S. Greenlees and Robert B. McClelland. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, August 2008. <www.bls.gov>

Pages 14–15:

One widely cited alternative index is based on an estimate that changes to the CPI since 1983 have lowered its growth rate by at least 7 percentage points per year. The use of the geometric mean alone is stated to have lowered the CPI growth rate by 3 percentage points, and other BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics] changes, such as the use of hedonic models and OER [owners’ equivalent rent], supposedly have lowered the growth rate by an additional 4 percentage points. …

… If the CPI were understated by 7 percentage points annually, then, from April 1998 to April 2008, prices would have risen by 155 percent, not 32 percent as reported by the CPI-U. Table 1 shows that a 7 percent difference implies unrealistic changes in price and income. First, the table presents examples of average prices published by the BLS from each of the six CPI grocery store food groups, along with four energy series. For example, the average price of a gallon of whole milk was $2.67 in April 1998 and $3.80 in April 2008. If the price had increased by 155 percent over that period, it would now be $6.81 per gallon. Similarly, if the average price of 2 liters of nondiet cola had increased by 155 percent over those 10 years, it would now be $2.72, more than twice as high as the actual April 2008 average price of $1.33. Of the 10 average prices listed in table 1, only two—gasoline and fuel oil—increased by such a large percentage.

Page 16: “Table 1. Comparisons of Prices and Incomes, April 1998 and April 2008 … Cola, nondiet, per 2 liters … April 1998 [=] 1.065 … April 2008 [=] 1.329 … April 2008 updates of 1998 values, assuming a 155-percent price increase [=] 2.72”

[140] Webpage: “About Us.” The Billion Prices Project. Accessed May 17, 2018 at <www.thebillionpricesproject.com>

“The Billion Prices Project is an academic initiative that uses prices collected from hundreds of online retailers around the world on a daily basis to conduct research in macro and international economics. It was founded in 2008 by Alberto Cavallo and Roberto Rigobon.”

[141] Paper: “The Billion Prices Project: Using Online Prices for Measurement and Research.” By Alberto Cavallo and Roberto Rigobon. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Spring 2016. Pages 151–178. <pubs.aeaweb.org>

Page 161: “Despite the multiple reasons why we might expect inflation indexes based on online and offline prices to deviate, the US online index has co-moved closely with the official Consumer Price Index for over seven years. Although there are periods where the indexes diverge, the differences are relatively small and temporary.”

[142] Article: “Inflation: Prices on the Rise.” By Ceyda Oner. International Monetary Fund. Updated July 29, 2017. <www.imf.org>

Indeed, many countries have grappled with high inflation—and in some cases hyperinflation, 1,000 percent or higher inflation a year. In 2008, Zimbabwe experienced one of the worst cases of hyperinflation ever, with estimated annual inflation at one point of 500 billion percent. Such high levels of inflation have been disastrous, and countries have had to take difficult and painful policy measures to bring inflation back to reasonable levels, sometimes by giving up their national currency, as Zimbabwe has.

If rapidly rising prices are bad for the economy, is the opposite, or falling prices, good? It turns out that deflation is not desirable either. When prices are falling, consumers delay making purchases if they can, anticipating lower prices in the future. For the economy this means less economic activity, less income generated by producers, and lower economic growth. Japan is one country with a long period of nearly no economic growth largely because of deflation. …

Most economists now believe that low, stable, and—most important—predictable inflation is good for an economy. If inflation is low and predictable, it is easier to capture it in price-adjustment contracts and interest rates, reducing its distortionary impact. Moreover, knowing that prices will be slightly higher in the future gives consumers an incentive to make purchases sooner, which boosts economic activity. Many central bankers have made their primary policy objective maintaining low and stable inflation, a policy called inflation targeting.

[143] Article: “How Does Inflation Affect Economies?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Ask Dr. Econ, March 2006. <www.frbsf.org>

Costs of Unexpected Inflation

1. Arbitrary redistribution of wealth from lenders to borrowers. When inflation turns out to be different from expectations, some groups can be made better off, while others can be made worse off. For instance, when inflation turns out to be higher than expected, lenders can realize losses, while borrowers can gain. …

2. Costs to individuals on fixed nominal contracts. Many long-term contracts build in an adjustment for inflation. People whose contract payments are fixed will suffer a loss in real terms (that is, in terms of purchasing power) if inflation turns out higher than they expected. For example, if pension payments are fixed for many periods and inflation ends up being higher than expected, then real pension payments end up being lower than expected.

[144] Article: “Inflation: Prices on the Rise.” By Ceyda Oner. International Monetary Fund. Updated July 29, 2017. <www.imf.org>

In reality, prices change at different paces. Some, such as the prices of traded commodities, change every day; others, such as wages established by contracts, take longer to adjust (or are “sticky,” in economic parlance). In an inflationary environment, unevenly rising prices inevitably reduce the purchasing power of some consumers, and this erosion of real income is the single biggest cost of inflation.

[145] Book: Study Guide to Accompany Macroeconomics (5th edition). By Robert J. Barro and Mark Rush. MIT Press, 1998.

Page 69:

Unexpected inflation, though, is a different story. After the saver and borrower have agreed on the nominal interest rate to be charged for the loan, they are committed. If the actual inflation rate exceeds what was expected when the loan was made, borrowers pay back the loan in dollars that have depreciated more than what was anticipated. As a result, the borrower gains because the repaid dollars purchase fewer goods than was contemplated when the loan agreement was signed. The lender is harmed by the unexpected inflation.

[146] Textbook: Macroeconomics (5th edition). By Robert J. Barro. MIT Press, 1997.

Page 294:

The general point is that unexpected inflation can have significant effects on the distribution of wealth.

The unpredictability of inflation reduces the willingness of people to enter into contracts that specify nominal values in advance. Thus … the usual types of bond and loan markets tended to disappear during the German hyperinflation and other extreme inflations. … [T]he loss of the traditional types of bonds and loans is an adverse real effect from unpredictable inflation. In particular, we would expect that the loss of these credit markets would hinder investment.

[147] Article: “The Impact of Inflation.” By Rebecca Hellerstein. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Regional Review, December 1, 1997. <www.bostonfed.org>

Inflation’s Inconveniences

Economists’ classic arguments about the inconveniences caused by inflation include: …

Menu Costs

Firms must alter their nominal prices to keep up with inflation. These adjustments require both time and money. The classic restaurant example underlines the time the manager must spend to set new prices and the money then spent to print new menus.

Shoe Leather Costs

People must spend more time searching for good prices when inflation is high, as relative prices may be more variable.

Economists generally consider the costs of these inconveniences as less significant than the costs due to inflation uncertainty.

[148] Article: “How Does Inflation Affect Economies?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Ask Dr. Econ, March 2006. <www.frbsf.org>

Increase in relative price volatility. These costs arise because firms facing menu costs are not likely to change prices frequently. As a result, relative price volatility increases. This, in turn, leads to inefficiencies in resource allocation. For more details, please see Example 2. …

Example 2—Increase in Relative Price Volatility

Suppose firm X produces one good and changes its price once a year (menu costs prevent this firm from changing its prices more often). In the case of no inflation in the economy (that is, the case when prices of other goods and services do not change), then the relative price of firm X’s good is constant throughout the year. Suppose, however, that inflation is 0.5% per month. In this case, prices of other goods and services increase by 0.5% every month, while the price of the good produced by firm X remains constant. Thus, the good produced by this firm becomes increasingly cheaper relative to other goods. In this scenario, sales of firm X might be relatively low at the beginning of the year (when the price of its good is relatively high) and increase towards the end of the year (as the relative price of its good falls). Economists believe that inefficiencies in resource allocation will result from this scenario.

[149] Article: “The Impact of Inflation.” By Rebecca Hellerstein. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Regional Review, December 1, 1997. <www.bostonfed.org>

Inflation’s Inconveniences

Economists’ classic arguments about the inconveniences caused by inflation include:

Deadweight Loss Costs

Holders of currency pay a kind of tax when inflation is positive and presumably they engage in real effort to minimize the amount and the time they hold it. With the advent of electronic forms of payment and credit cards, deadweight losses are considered less significant than in the past.

[150] Article: “Why Do People Dislike Inflation?” By Yi Wen. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Monetary Trends, June 2010. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Economists have often puzzled over the costs of inflation. …

… The argument is that nominal income can adjust for anticipated inflation, leaving people almost as well off as they would have been in the absence of inflation except for the opportunity cost of holding non-interest-bearing cash. Hence, economists commonly measure the cost of inflation as the area under the money demand function, which reflects the deadweight loss of holding cash instead of interest-bearing assets. By this measure, inflation has surprisingly small costs: about 0.1 to 0.8 percent of consumption when the inflation rate is 10 percent per year. …

Why do economists and ordinary people view the costs of inflation so differently? … One is that standard economic measures may have failed to fully capture the costs of inflation. … Wen (2010) argues that the standard economic measure of the costs of inflation does not take into account the insurance (buffer-stock) function of money. Since inflation destroys the value of money and reduces the demand for cash, it exposes people (especially low-income households) to more consumption variability than otherwise. Based on this concept, Wen finds that the cost of 10 percent annual inflation is equivalent to the loss of 8 to 12 percent of consumption (or income).

[151] Article: “Deflation: Who Let the Air Out?” By Hoda El-Ghazaly. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, February 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

At the same time, borrowing by businesses for investment or by households for big-ticket items (i.e., cars and homes) becomes equally unattractive. For example, consider a $100 loan at a 2 percent interest rate with full payment, $102, due at the end of the year. If during the year there is 5 percent inflation (the price level increases), only $97 in real terms is owed at the end of the year because the money borrowed now purchases fewer goods and services. Alternatively, if during the year there is 5 percent deflation (the price level decreases), then $107 dollars in real terms is owed at the end of the year because the money borrowed now purchases more goods and services. Because of its potential to cause such an increase in the real cost of borrowing, deflation could cause further pain to an already hard-hit U.S. housing sector as households continue delaying home purchases to circumvent such losses.

[152] Article: “Deflation: Who Let the Air Out?” By Hoda El-Ghazaly. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, February 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

“While the idea of lower prices may sound attractive, deflation is a real concern for several reasons. Deflation discourages spending and investment because consumers, expecting prices to fall further, delay purchases, preferring instead to save and wait for even lower prices.”

[153] Book: Deflation: Current and Historical Perspectives. Edited by Richard C. K. Burdekin and Pierre L. Siklos. Cambridge University Press, 2004.

Page 4: “[A]nother reason to fear deflation in consumer prices is that, if it is expected that such declining prices will continue in the future, there is an incentive to delay purchases. This then leads to a further decline in aggregate demand, putting further downward pressure on prices and suggesting that deflation could be at least partially self-sustaining.

[154] Article: “Deflation: Who Let the Air Out?” By Hoda El-Ghazaly. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, February 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

“Deflation discourages spending and investment because consumers, expecting prices to fall further, delay purchases, preferring instead to save and wait for even lower prices. Decreased spending, in turn, lowers company sales and profits, which eventually increases unemployment.”

[155] Article: “Understanding Deflation.” By Tao Wu. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letters, April 2, 2004. <www.frbsf.org>

Second, the labor market adjustment may be more difficult. During a recession, unemployment is typically higher, as the demand for workers is weak. In order to boost employment, nominal wages need to fall. But workers are typically very resistant to accepting wage reductions in nominal terms. Therefore real wages tend not to decline to the level required to “clear the market,” and, as a result the job losses in this situation might be greater than in a modest inflation. This may prolong the recession on several counts. It could affect factors like consumer confidence, thereby weakening aggregate demand. It also could discourage firms from increasing employment, given that product prices and profit margins are shrinking.

[156] Article: “How the Fed Seeks to Influence Interest Rates.” By Charles Davidson. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economy Matters, July 11, 2017. <www.frbatlanta.org>

It mostly comes down to one number.

That number is the federal funds rate, the interest rate financial institutions charge one another for overnight loans made from balances held at Federal Reserve banks.

But when the Fed’s policy-setting Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) decides to adjust the fed funds rate, not all interest rates throughout the economy change instantaneously. Rather, monetary policy is “transmitted,” through various channels, to an array of very short-term interest rates and financial market prices. These changes, in turn, ripple through the financial system to influence rates on all kinds of loans to consumers and businesses.

Simply put, when interest rates rise, people tend to borrow less and prices tend to stabilize. When interest rates fall, people and businesses tend to borrow and spend more, which can stimulate the economy.

[157] Webpage: “How Does Monetary Policy Influence Inflation and Employment?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated December 16, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

During normal times, the Federal Reserve has primarily influenced overall financial conditions by adjusting the federal funds rate—the rate that banks charge each other for short-term loans. Movements in the federal funds rate are passed on to other short-term interest rates that influence borrowing costs for firms and households. Movements in short-term interest rates also influence long-term interest rates—such as corporate bond rates and residential mortgage rates—because those rates reflect, among other factors, the current and expected future values of short-term rates. …

In turn, these changes in financial conditions affect economic activity. For example, when short- and long-term interest rates go down, it becomes cheaper to borrow, so households are more willing to buy goods and services and firms are in a better position to purchase items to expand their businesses, such as property and equipment. …

Monetary policy also has an important influence on inflation. When the federal funds rate is reduced, the resulting stronger demand for goods and services tends to push wages and other costs higher, reflecting the greater demand for workers and materials that are necessary for production.

[158] Webpage: “Quantitative Easing.” Bank of England. Last updated January 24, 2018. <www.bankofengland.co.uk>

“Quantitative easing is when a central bank like the Bank of England creates new money electronically to make large purchases of assets.”

[159] Article: “Quantitative Easing Explained.” By Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, April 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 1:

In late 2008, in response to rapidly deteriorating economic and financial conditions, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) pushed the federal funds rate target1 close to zero. As conditions worsened, the Fed turned to nontraditional policies to bolster financial market conditions. Such policies include large-scale asset purchases—in the hundreds of billions of dollars range—of, for example, mortgage-backed securities2 and Treasury securities. This action is commonly called “quantitative easing” (QE).

[160] Speech: “The Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August 27, 2010. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] has also acted to improve market functioning and to push longer-term interest rates lower through its large-scale purchases of agency debt, agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and longer-term Treasury securities, of which the Federal Reserve currently holds more than $2 trillion. The channels through which the Fed’s purchases affect longer-term interest rates and financial conditions more generally have been subject to debate. I see the evidence as most favorable to the view that such purchases work primarily through the so-called portfolio balance channel, which holds that once short-term interest rates have reached zero, the Federal Reserve’s purchases of longer-term securities affect financial conditions by changing the quantity and mix of financial assets held by the public. Specifically, the Fed’s strategy relies on the presumption that different financial assets are not perfect substitutes in investors' portfolios, so that changes in the net supply of an asset available to investors affect its yield and those of broadly similar assets. Thus, our purchases of Treasury, agency debt, and agency MBS likely both reduced the yields on those securities and also pushed investors into holding other assets with similar characteristics, such as credit risk and duration. For example, some investors who sold MBS to the Fed may have replaced them in their portfolios with longer-term, high-quality corporate bonds, depressing the yields on those assets as well.

[161] Article: “Quantitative Easing: How Well Does This Tool Work?” By Stephen D. Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, 2017. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Pages 9–11:

Quantitative easing (QE)—large-scale purchases of assets by central banks—led to a large increase in the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet during the global financial crisis (2007–2008) and in the long recovery from the 2008–2009 recession. … QE consists of large-scale asset purchases by central banks, usually of long-maturity government debt but also of private assets, such as corporate debt or asset-backed securities. Typically, QE occurs in unconventional circumstances, when short-term nominal interest rates are very low, zero or even negative. …

Traditionally, the interest rate that the Fed targets is the federal funds (fed funds) rate. Suppose, though, that the fed funds rate target is zero, but inflation is below the Fed’s 2 percent target and aggregate output is lower than potential. If the effective lower bound were not a binding constraint, the Fed would choose to lower the fed funds rate target, but it cannot. What then? The Fed faced such a situation at the end of 2008, during the financial crisis, and resorted to unconventional monetary policy, including a series of QE experiments that continued into late 2014. …

At the 2010 Jackson Hole conference, then-Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke attempted to articulate the Fed’s rationale for QE. Bernanke’s view was that, with short-term nominal interest rates at zero, purchases by the central bank of long-maturity assets would act to push up the prices of those securities because the Fed was reducing their net supply. Thus, long-maturity bond yields should go down, for example, if the Fed purchases long-maturity Treasury securities.

[162] Article: “Quantitative Easing Explained.” By Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, April 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 1: “QE [Quantitative Easing] is not a new approach; it was used by the Fed in the 1930s,5 the Bank of Japan in 2001,6 and more recently by the Bank of England.”

[163] Article: “Great Depression.” By Richard H. Pells and Christina D. Romer. Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

Great Depression, worldwide economic downturn that began in 1929 and lasted until about 1939. It was the longest and most severe depression ever experienced by the industrialized Western world, sparking fundamental changes in economic institutions, macroeconomic policy, and economic theory.”

[164] Article: “Quantitative Easing: How Well Does This Tool Work?” by Stephen D. Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, 2017. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 9: “Quantitative easing (QE)—large-scale purchases of assets by central banks—led to a large increase in the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet during the global financial crisis (2007–2008) and in the long recovery from the 2008–2009 recession.”

[165] Report: “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, September 20, 2010. <www.nber.org>

“Contractions (recessions) start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. … Peak [=] December 2007 (IV) … Trough [=] June 2009 (II)”

[166] Entry: “Gold Standard.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

“Gold standard, monetary system in which the standard unit of currency is a fixed quantity of gold or is kept at the value of a fixed quantity of gold. The currency is freely convertible at home or abroad into a fixed amount of gold per unit of currency”

[167] Entry: “Fiat Money.” Encyclopedia Britannica, February 3, 2017. <www.britannica.com>

“Fiat money, in a broad sense, all kinds of money that are made legal tender by a government decree or fiat. The term is, however, usually reserved for legal-tender paper money or coins that have face values far exceeding their commodity values and are not redeemable in gold or silver.”

[168] Speech: “The Future of Money and of Monetary Policy.” By Laurence H. Meyer. The Federal Reserve Board, December 5, 2001. <www.federalreserve.gov>

With the collapse of the gold standard, countries moved to fiat money systems. Fiat money is inconvertible, meaning that it is not convertible into nor backed by any commodity. It serves as legal tender by decree, or fiat, of the government. Its value is based on trust—specifically that others will accept it in payment for goods and services and that its value will remain relatively stable. This trust is based, in part, on laws that make the fiat money “legal tender” in the payment of taxes and, in the United States, also in the payment of private debts.3

3 Section 102 of the Coinage Act of 1965 provides in part: “All coins and currencies of the United States, regardless of when coined or issued, shall be legal tender for all debts, public and private, public charges, taxes, duties, and dues.” Thus when you tender U.S. currency to your creditor, you have made a legal offer to pay your debts. However, private businesses are not required to accept currency as a form of payment and may develop their own policies in this respect, unless state law says otherwise. However, the government is required to accept currency in payment of taxes and for other public charges.

[169] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Pages 143–144:

Henry [II]’s reform restored the prestige of English money, the quality of which was jealously safeguarded from any further major decline until the mid-sixteenth century. This was so unlike the situation on the Continent that the term “the pound sterling” emerged into common usage with its well-known praiseworthy connotations. …

… Hence “sterling” would be the natural description for English money, which from the tenth century onward tended generally to be of higher quality than that of its continental neighbours, and therefore referred specifically to the penny coins weighing 22 1/2 grains troy of silver at least pure to 925 parts in a thousand, 240 of which made the Tower pound weight or the pound sterling in value. It is also significant to note that the term “pound sterling” was in common use throughout Europe in the Middle Ages, with all its connotations of solidity, stability and quality—long before the issue of a pound coin—when silver was almost the only metal used in British coinage and the penny was almost the only, and certainly the main, coin. … So long as full-bodied gold and silver coins were issued in Britain, that is right up to the First World War, so long did the term “the pound sterling” maintain its prestigious significance, that is for a period spanning well over 800 years, from 1078 to 1914.

[170] Article: “A Short History of the British Pound.” By Chris Parker. World Economic Forum, June 27, 2016. <www.weforum.org>

1717

The United Kingdom defined sterling’s value in terms of gold rather than silver for the first time.

Sir Isaac Newton, as Master of the Mint, set the gold price of £4.25 per fine ounce that lasted two hundred years, except during the Napoleonic wars when gold cash payments were suspended.

[171] Entry: “Fiat Money.” Encyclopedia Britannica, February 3, 2017. <www.britannica.com>

Throughout history, paper money and banknotes had traditionally acted as promises to pay the bearer a specified amount of a precious metal, typically silver or gold. The continental currency issued during the American Revolution, the assignats issued during the French Revolution, the “greenbacks” of the American Civil War period, and the paper marks issued in Germany in the early 1920s are historical examples of fiat money. These episodes marked deviations from the gold standard or bimetallic systems that prevailed from the early 19th through the mid-20th century.

[172] Webpage: “Independence.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Accessed September 22, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

Beginning in 1775, the Continental Congress issued currency to finance the Revolutionary War. These notes, called Continentals, had no backing in gold or silver.

Continentals were backed by the “anticipation” of tax revenues. Easily counterfeited and without solid backing, the notes quickly became devalued, giving rise to the phrase “not worth a Continental.” This brief period marked the first time that U.S. currency’s value was derived solely from its purchasing power, as it is today.

[173] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 469:

That Act [the Coinage Act of 1792] officially adopted the dollar as the American unit of account (so confirming Confederate legislation). … Thirdly, the dollar was officially to be bimetallist, being defined as equivalent to 371.25 grains of silver or 24.75 grains of gold. The mint ratio was thus 15:1—a rate that in practice was found slightly to overvalue silver.

[174] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 488: “Priority in the use of the nation’s supply of gold and silver was given for government purposes, and the drain of specie from the banks led to the formal declaration of suspension by Congress at the end of December 1861.”

[175] Entry: “Fiat Money.” Encyclopedia Britannica, February 3, 2017. <www.britannica.com>

Throughout history, paper money and banknotes had traditionally acted as promises to pay the bearer a specified amount of a precious metal, typically silver or gold. The … “greenbacks” of the American Civil War period … are historical examples of fiat money. These episodes marked deviations from the gold standard or bimetallic systems that prevailed from the early 19th through the mid-20th century.

[176] Entry: “Resumption Act of 1875.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

On Jan. 14, 1875, Congress passed the Resumption Act, which called for the secretary of the Treasury to redeem legal-tender notes in specie beginning Jan. 1, 1879. … Specie resumption proceeded on schedule, however, and Treasury Secretary John Sherman accumulated enough gold to meet the expected demand. When the public realized that the paper money was “good as gold,” there was no rush to redeem, and greenbacks continued as the accepted currency.

[177] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 496:

Around the same time [1878] two further aspects of the money question were being resolved, namely the demonetization of silver and the resumption of convertibility into specie, the specie concerned being gold. By the Coinage Act of 1873 … the USA was now virtually on the gold standard. The gold premium carried by notes was clearly falling during the early 1870s, so that the government felt it safe, by the Resumption Act of January 1875, to promise full redemption by 1 January 1879.

[178] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 356:

In 1816 gold became at last legally recognized as the official standard of value for the pound, though it was not until the restoration of convertibility in 1821 that the domestic gold standard was in full operation. We have also traced how the Bank of England came to be the monopolistic issuer of bank notes with a fixed fiduciary issue of £14 million and also came to hold the main gold reserves of the centralizing banking system.

[179] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 357:

[T]he major trading countries had become so favourably impressed [with Britain’s management of the gold standard] that they too gave up their flirtations with silver and bimetallism and adopted full gold standards with internal circulation of full-bodied gold coinage and more or less freely allowed imports and exports of gold, as the rules of the international gold standard system demanded. Following the new German Empire’s decision in 1871 to base its mark on gold, Holland, Austro–Hungary, Russia and the Scandinavian countries soon did likewise, while in 1878 France abandoned its bimetallic experiments in favour of gold. Thus by the end of the 1870s, without being consciously planned, the international gold standard system had fallen fittingly into place (though internally the USA still flirted with bimetallism).

[180] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Pages 498–499:

[G]old supplies helped to stimulate the world economy and led to a doubling of America’s monetary gold stock from 1890 to 1900 (and a trebling between the earlier date and 1914). This was the economic reality that moved the balance of opinion decisively away from bimetallism and led at last to the confident enactment of the Gold Standard Act of March 1900: gold monometallism had, belatedly, legally captured what was to be its most powerful convert.

[181] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

“The period from 1880 to 1914 is known as the classical gold standard. During that time, the majority of countries adhered (in varying degrees) to gold. It was also a period of unprecedented economic growth with relatively free trade in goods, labor, and capital.”

[182] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

The United States, though formally on a bimetallic (gold and silver) standard, switched to gold de facto in 1834 and de jure in 1900 when Congress passed the Gold Standard Act. In 1834, the United States fixed the price of gold at $20.67 per ounce, where it remained until 1933. Other major countries joined the gold standard in the 1870s. The period from 1880 to 1914 is known as the classical gold standard. During that time, the majority of countries adhered (in varying degrees) to gold. It was also a period of unprecedented economic growth with relatively free trade in goods, labor, and capital.

[183] Article: “The Classical Gold Standard: Some Lessons for Today.” By Michael D. Bordo. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, May 1981. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 7:

By 1880, the majority of countries in the world were on some form of a gold standard. The period from 1880 to 1914, known as the heyday of the gold standard, was a remarkable period in world economic history. It was characterized by rapid economic growth, the free flow of labor and capital across political borders, virtually free trade and, in general, world peace. These external conditions, coupled with the elaborate financial network centered in London and the role of the Bank of England as umpire to the system, are believed to be the sine qua non of the effective operation of the gold standard.

[184] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

The gold standard was a domestic standard regulating the quantity and growth rate of a country’s money supply. Because new production of gold would add only a small fraction to the accumulated stock, and because the authorities guaranteed free convertibility of gold into nongold money, the gold standard ensured that the money supply, and hence the price level, would not vary much.

[185] Entry: “Gold Standard.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

In an international gold-standard system, gold or a currency that is convertible into gold at a fixed price is used as a medium of international payments. Under such a system, exchange rates between countries are fixed; if exchange rates rise above or fall below the fixed mint rate by more than the cost of shipping gold from one country to another, large gold inflows or outflows occur until the rates return to the official level.

[186] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

Because exchange rates were fixed, the gold standard caused price levels around the world to move together. This comovement occurred mainly through an automatic balance-of-payments adjustment process called the price-specie-flow mechanism. Here is how the mechanism worked. Suppose that a technological innovation brought about faster real economic growth in the United States. Because the supply of money (gold) essentially was fixed in the short run, U.S. prices fell. Prices of U.S. exports then fell relative to the prices of imports. This caused the British to demand more U.S. exports and Americans to demand fewer imports. A U.S. balance-of-payments surplus was created, causing gold (specie) to flow from the United Kingdom to the United States. The gold inflow increased the U.S. money supply, reversing the initial fall in prices. In the United Kingdom, the gold outflow reduced the money supply and, hence, lowered the price level. The net result was balanced prices among countries.

[187] Article: “The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal.” By Leland Crabbe. Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

To be on the gold standard a country needed to maintain the convertibility between notes and gold and to allow gold to flow freely across its borders. In the early days of the war, Austria, Hungary, France, Germany, and Russia all went off the gold standard as they suspended specie payments and instituted legal or de facto embargoes on the export of gold by private citizens. Like the British Treasury, the governments of these warring countries exported gold and borrowed heavily to finance the war, but these tactics raised only a fraction of the large sums of money that the war required. Because new taxes did not and could not make up the difference, the continental belligerents financed a large share of the war by printing money, which caused prices to soar and complicated the return of these countries to the gold standard after the war.

[188] Article: “The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal.” By Leland Crabbe. Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 426: “In 1919, almost every country regarded the gold standard as an essential institution; but, among the world powers, only the United States could be counted as a gold-standard country. … By default, the Federal Reserve assumed the office of manager of the gold standard.”

[189] Article: “The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal.” By Leland Crabbe. Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 429: “After the war, Britain and all European countries wanted to restore the legal gold-backing for their currencies. … Although determined to restore the prewar gold parity, the British had to wait for price deflation and sterling appreciation. While they waited, the formal embargo of exports on gold protected the Bank of England’s gold reserve.”

Page 431:

On April 28, 1925, Winston Churchill, then Chancellor of the Exchequer, returned Britain to the gold standard by announcing that the Gold and Silver (Export Control) Act, which was due to expire at year-end, would not be renewed. On May 13, Parliament passed the Gold Standard Act of 1925, which obligated the Bank of England to sell gold bullion in exchange for notes at the prewar par of 77s. 10.5d. per standard ounce. At the end of 1925, thirty-nine countries had returned to par, had devalued their currency, or had achieved de facto stabilization with the dollar.

[190] Article: “The Classical Gold Standard: Some Lessons for Today.” By Michael D. Bordo. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, May 1981. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 7:

The gold standard broke down during World War I, was succeeded by a period of “managed fiduciary money,” and was briefly reinstated from 1925 to 1931 as the Gold Exchange Standard. Under the Gold Exchange Standard, countries could hold both gold and dollars or pounds as reserves, except for the United States and the United Kingdom, which held reserves only in gold. In addition, most countries engaged in active sterilization policies to protect their domestic money supplies from gold flows.

The Gold Exchange Standard broke down in 1931 following Britain’s departure from gold in the face of massive gold and capital flows and was again succeeded by managed fiduciary money.

[191] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

The gold standard broke down during World War I, as major belligerents resorted to inflationary finance, and was briefly reinstated from 1925 to 1931 as the Gold Exchange Standard. … This version broke down in 1931 following Britain’s departure from gold in the face of massive gold and capital outflows. In 1933, President Franklin D. Roosevelt nationalized gold owned by private citizens and abrogated contracts in which payment was specified in gold.

[192] Entry: “Great Depression.” By Richard H. Pells and Christina D. Romer. Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

Great Depression, worldwide economic downturn that began in 1929 and lasted until about 1939. It was the longest and most severe depression ever experienced by the industrialized Western world, sparking fundamental changes in economic institutions, macroeconomic policy, and economic theory. …

… Great Britain struggled with low growth and recession during most of the second half of the 1920s. Britain did not slip into severe depression, however, until early 1930, and its peak-to-trough decline in industrial production was roughly one-third that of the United States. …

… The British economy stopped declining soon after Great Britain abandoned the gold standard in September 1931, although genuine recovery did not begin until the end of 1932.

[193] Article: “A Short History of the British Pound.” By Chris Parker. World Economic Forum, June 27, 2016. <www.weforum.org>

1931

Sterling came off the gold standard and the pound promptly dropped considerably.

£1 equivalent to $3.69.

[194] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 389:

When sterling went off gold, almost all those countries which carried on the lion’s share of their trade with Britain followed Britain off gold—otherwise they would have priced their goods out of the large market which Britain provided. These countries included all the Commonwealth (except Canada), Ireland, the Scandinavian countries, Egypt, Iraq, Portugal and Siam (Thailand), and a number of South American countries like Argentina.

[195] Article: “Creation of the Bretton Woods System.” By Sandra Kollen Ghizoni. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

A new international monetary system was forged by delegates from forty-four nations in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, in July 1944. … The countries agreed to keep their currencies fixed but adjustable (within a 1 percent band) to the dollar, and the dollar was fixed to gold at $35 an ounce. …

In 1958, the Bretton Woods system became fully functional as currencies became convertible. Countries settled international balances in dollars, and US dollars were convertible to gold at a fixed exchange rate of $35 an ounce. The United States had the responsibility of keeping the price of gold fixed and had to adjust the supply of dollars to maintain confidence in future gold convertibility.

[196] Article: “The Classical Gold Standard: Some Lessons for Today.” By Michael D. Bordo. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, May 1981. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 7:

The Bretton Woods System: 1946–71

The Bretton Woods System was an attempt to return to a modified gold standard using the U.S. dollar as the world’s key reserve currency. All other countries—except for the sterling bloc—settled their international balances in dollars. The United States fixed the price of gold at $35.00 per ounce, maintained substantial gold reserves, and settled external accounts with gold bullion payments and receipts. …

However, the steady growth in the use of U.S. dollars as international reserves and persistent U.S. deficits steadily reduced U.S. gold reserves and the gold reserve ratio, reducing public confidence in the ultimate ability of the United States to redeem its currency in gold. … The U.S. decision in 1971 to abandon pegging the price of gold was the final demise of the gold standard.

[197] Article: “The Great Inflation.” By Michael Bryan. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

As the world’s reserve currency, the U.S. dollar had an additional problem. As global trade grew, so too did the demand for U.S. dollar reserves. For a time, the demand for U.S. dollars was satisfied by an increasing balance of payments shortfall, and foreign central banks accumulated more and more dollar reserves. Eventually, the supply of dollar reserves held abroad exceeded the U.S. stock of gold, implying that the United States could not maintain complete convertibility at the existing price of gold—a fact that would not go unnoticed by foreign governments and currency speculators.

As inflation drifted higher during the latter half of the 1960s, U.S. dollars were increasingly converted to gold, and in the summer of 1971, President Nixon halted the exchange of dollars for gold by foreign central banks. …

With the last link to gold severed, most of the world’s currencies, including the US dollar, were now completely unanchored. Except during periods of global crisis, this was the first time in history that most of the monies of the industrialized world were on an irredeemable paper money standard.

[198] Entry: “Fiat Money.” Encyclopedia Britannica, February 3, 2017. <www.britannica.com>

By the late 20th century, it had become impossible for the United States to maintain gold at a fixed rate, and in August 1971, U.S. Pres. Richard M. Nixon announced that he would “suspend temporarily the convertibility of the dollar into gold or other reserve assets.” In fact, the move spelled the end of the Bretton Woods system and the last vestiges of the gold standard. Within two years, most major currencies “floated,” rising and falling in value against one another based on market demand.

[199] Entry: “Exchange Rate.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

An exchange rate is “floating” when supply and demand or speculation sets exchange rates (conversion units). If a country imports large quantities of goods, the demand will push up the exchange rate for that country, making the imported goods more expensive to buyers in that country. As the goods become more expensive, demand drops, and that country’s money becomes cheaper in relation to the other countries’ money. Then the country’s good become cheaper to buyers abroad, demand rises, and exports from the country increase.

World trade now depends on a managed floating exchange system. Governments act to stabilize their countries’ exchange rates by limiting imports, stimulating exports, or devaluing currencies.

[200] Webpage: “Monetary Policy Principles and Practice: Historical Approaches to Monetary Policy.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 8, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Prominent Historical Examples of Nominal Anchors

One prominent example is the gold standard, which, at the time the Federal Reserve was founded in 1913, served as the nominal anchor for much of the world, including the United States. Under the gold standard, the central bank commits to exchanging, on demand, a unit of domestic currency (for example, one dollar) for a fixed quantity of gold. As a result, the amount of money in the economy rises or falls in correspondence with the amount of gold in the central bank’s vaults. If gold production keeps up with economic growth and the gold-currency convertibility is dutifully maintained, the price level can be expected to be roughly stable.

[201] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

The gold standard was a domestic standard regulating the quantity and growth rate of a country’s money supply. Because new production of gold would add only a small fraction to the accumulated stock, and because the authorities guaranteed free convertibility of gold into nongold money, the gold standard ensured that the money supply, and hence the price level, would not vary much.

[202] Webpage: “Monetary Policy Principles and Practice: Historical Approaches to Monetary Policy.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 8, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“In the case of the gold standard, the maintenance of convertibility on demand between currency and gold was not always consistent with price stability. The United States tended to experience deflation when gold production did not keep up with the pace of economic expansion and, conversely, to experience inflation when gold production ran ahead of economic growth.”

[203] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

An example of a monetary shock was the California gold discovery in 1848. The newly produced gold increased the U.S. money supply, which then raised domestic expenditures, nominal income, and, ultimately, the price level. The rise in the domestic price level made U.S. exports more expensive, causing a deficit in the U.S. balance of payments. For America’s trading partners, the same forces necessarily produced a balance-of-trade surplus. The U.S. trade deficit was financed by a gold (specie) outflow to its trading partners, reducing the monetary gold stock in the United States. In the trading partners, the money supply increased, raising domestic expenditures, nominal incomes, and, ultimately, the price level. Depending on the relative share of the U.S. monetary gold stock in the world total, world prices and income rose. Although the initial effect of the gold discovery was to increase real output (because wages and prices did not immediately increase), eventually the full effect was on the price level alone. …

But because economies under the gold standard were so vulnerable to real and monetary shocks, prices were highly unstable in the short run. A measure of short-term price instability is the coefficient of variation, which is the ratio of the standard deviation of annual percentage changes in the price level to the average annual percentage change. The higher the coefficient of variation, the greater the short-term instability. For the United States between 1879 and 1913, the coefficient was 17.0, which is quite high. Between 1946 and 1990 it was only 0.8.

[204] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

Widespread dissatisfaction with high inflation in the late 1970s and early 1980s brought renewed interest in the gold standard. Although that interest is not strong today, it seems to strengthen every time inflation moves much above 6 percent. This makes sense. Whatever other problems there were with the gold standard, persistent inflation was not one of them. Between 1880 and 1914, the period when the United States was on the “classical gold standard,” inflation averaged only 0.1 percent per year. …

As mentioned, the great virtue of the gold standard was that it assured long-term price stability. Compare the aforementioned average annual inflation rate of 0.1 percent between 1880 and 1914 with the average of 4.2 percent between 1946 and 1990. (The reason for excluding the period from 1914 to 1946 is that it was neither a period of the classical gold standard nor a period during which governments understood how to manage monetary policy.)

[205] Article: “Money.” By Stephen Clayton. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Everyday Economics, November 2015. <www.dallasfed.org>

Pages 10–13:

Since fiat money is not based on an underlying supply of a scarce commodity, the responsibility to maintain its scarcity lies in a regulating body. For the money to remain acceptable, that regulating body must keep the appropriate amount of money in circulation to protect its value. …

If a regulating body makes too much available, inflation—the general rise of prices in the economy—can occur. If not enough money is available, growth in the economy can be constrained. Balancing between not enough money in circulation and too much money in circulation has proven difficult for some countries.

[206] Webpage: “Monetary Policy Principles and Practice: Historical Approaches to Monetary Policy.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 8, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Today the nominal anchor in the United States is the Federal Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) explicit objective of achieving inflation at the rate of 2 percent per year over the longer run. This goal is supported by a policy strategy by which the FOMC responds to economic developments in a way that systematically aims to return inflation to 2 percent over time. By aiming to achieve low and stable inflation (as opposed to maintaining a particular price of gold or foreign exchange or a particular growth rate of the money supply), the FOMC has the flexibility to adapt its strategy as its understanding of the economy improves and as economic relationships evolve.

[207] Webpage: “Monetary Policy: What Are Its Goals? How Does It Work?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 8, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

In the broadest terms, monetary policy works by spurring or restraining growth of overall demand for goods and services in the economy. When overall demand slows relative to the economy’s capacity to produce goods and services, unemployment tends to rise and inflation tends to decline. The FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] can help stabilize the economy in the face of these developments by stimulating overall demand through an easing of monetary policy that lowers interest rates. Conversely, when overall demand for goods and services is too strong, unemployment can fall to unsustainably low levels and inflation can rise. In such a situation, the Fed can guide economic activity back to more sustainable levels and keep inflation in check by tightening monetary policy to raise interest rates.

[208] Webpage: “Currency: The Federal Reserve Board’s Role.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated February 8, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

As the issuing authority for all Federal Reserve notes, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System has a wide range of responsibilities related to paper money, from ensuring an adequate supply to protecting and maintaining confidence in our currency. Together with our partners at the Treasury Department, its Bureau of Engraving and Printing, and the United States Secret Service, we continuously monitor the counterfeiting threats for each denomination and make redesign decisions based on these threats.

[209] Calculated with data from:

a) Book: Handbook of Labor Statistics 1971. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1971.

Page 253: “Table 111. Consumer Price Index, U.S. City Average for All Items, 1800–1970 and for Selected Groups, and Purchasing Power of the Consumer Dollar, 1913–70 (1967=100)”

b) Dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[210] Entry: “Exchange Rate.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

“Exchange rate, the price of a country’s money in relation to another country’s money.”

[211] Paper: “Exchange Rates, International Trade and Trade Policies.” By Alessandro Nicita. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Policy Issues in International Trade and Commodities, 2013. <unctad.org>

Page iii: “The exchange rate plays an important role in a country’s trade performance. Whether determined by exogenous shocks or by policy, the relative valuations of currencies and their volatility often have important repercussions on international trade, the balance of payments and overall economic performance.”

[212] Article: “International Payment and Exchange.” By Roy Forbes Harrod, Francis S. Pierce, and Paul Wonnacott. Encyclopedia Britannica, March 14, 2016. <www.britannica.com>

During the late 1970s, the U.S. dollar was threatened with a collapse. By the mid-1980s the opposite had occurred: the dollar had soared—rising about 80 percent. A number of forces contributed to this rise. One was U.S. fiscal policy: tax rates were cut sharply, and budgetary deficits ballooned. Large-scale government borrowing added to the demands on financial markets, leading to high interest rates. This encouraged foreign asset holders to buy U.S. bonds. To do so, they bought dollars, creating upward pressure on the exchange value of the dollar. In turn, the high dollar made it difficult for U.S. producers to compete on world markets. U.S. imports rose briskly; exports were relatively sluggish, and the U.S. trade deficit soared.

Because of strong competition from imports, U.S. producers of automobiles, textiles, and a number of other products lobbied for protection. Under the threat of unilateral U.S. actions, the government of Japan was persuaded to impose “voluntary” limits on exports of cars to the United States. There were concerns—both in the United States and in its trading partners—that the United States might adopt a much more protectionist policy because the high exchange value of the dollar was making it so difficult for U.S. producers to compete.

[213] Paper: “Exchange Rates, International Trade and Trade Policies.” By Alessandro Nicita. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Policy Issues in International Trade and Commodities, 2013. <unctad.org>

Page 14: “In more detail, the results indicate that exchange rate misalignments do affect international trade flows in a substantial manner. Currency undervaluation is found to promote exports and restrict imports, while the converse holds in the case of overvaluation. In magnitude, misalignments across currencies result in trade diversion quantifiable in about 1 per cent of world trade.”

[214] Webpage: “U.S. Foreign Exchange Intervention.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, May 2007. <www.newyorkfed.org>

[S]uppose the price of the Japanese yen moves from 120 yen per dollar to 110 yen per dollar over the course of a few weeks. In market parlance, the yen is “strengthening” or “appreciating” against the dollar, which means it is becoming more expensive in dollar terms. If the new exchange rate persists, it will lead to several related effects. First, Japanese exports to the United States will become more expensive. Over time, this might cause export volumes to the United States to decline, which, in turn, might lead to job losses for exporters in Japan. Also, the higher U.S. import prices might be an inflationary influence in the United States. Finally, U.S. exports to Japan will become less expensive, which might lead to an increase in U.S. exports and a boost to U.S. employment.

[215] Report: “World Economic Outlook: Adjusting to Lower Commodity Prices.” International Monetary Fund, October 2015. <www.imf.org>

Page 111:

What do the estimates for price and volume elasticities imply for the overall effect of exchange rate movements on net exports? … The results suggest that a 10 percent real effective depreciation in an economy’s currency is associated with a rise in real net exports of, on average, 1.5 percent of GDP, with substantial cross-country variation around this average (Figure 3.3). Given the wide range of GDP shares of exports and imports across economies, this implied effect of a real effective depreciation of 10 percent ranges from 0.5 percent of GDP to 3.1 percent of GDP. Although it takes a number of years for these effects to fully materialize, much of the adjustment occurs in the first year, as mentioned.22

[216] Webpage: “U.S. Foreign Exchange Intervention.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, May 2007. <www.newyorkfed.org>

[S]uppose the price of the Japanese yen moves from 120 yen per dollar to 110 yen per dollar over the course of a few weeks. In market parlance, the yen is “strengthening” or “appreciating” against the dollar, which means it is becoming more expensive in dollar terms. If the new exchange rate persists, it will lead to several related effects. First, Japanese exports to the United States will become more expensive. Over time, this might cause export volumes to the United States to decline, which, in turn, might lead to job losses for exporters in Japan. Also, the higher U.S. import prices might be an inflationary influence in the United States. Finally, U.S. exports to Japan will become less expensive, which might lead to an increase in U.S. exports and a boost to U.S. employment.

[217] Textbook: Macroeconomics: A Contemporary Introduction (10th edition). By William A. McEachern. South-Western Cengage Learning, 2014.

Page 416:

[F]lexible exchange rates have often been volatile. This volatility creates uncertainty and risk for importers and exporters, increasing the transaction costs of international trade. Furthermore, exchange rate volatility can lead to wrenching changes in the competitiveness of a country’s export sector. These changes cause swings in employment, resulting in louder calls for import restrictions. For example, the exchange rate between the Japanese yen and the U.S. dollar has been relatively unstable, particularly because of international speculation.

[218] Entry: “Devaluation.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

Devaluation, reduction in the exchange value of a country’s monetary unit in terms of gold, silver, or foreign monetary units. Devaluation is employed to eliminate persistent balance-of-payments deficits. For example, a devaluation of currency will decrease prices of the home country’s exports that are purchased in the import country’s currency. While making the exported goods cheaper for other countries, devaluation also increases the prices of imports purchased in the home country. If the demand for both exports and imports is relatively elastic (that is, the quantity purchased is highly responsive to changes in price), the country’s income from exports will rise, and its expenditure for imports will fall. Thus, its trade will be more in balance and its balance of payments improved.

[219] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 395: “Intensified speculation against the pound in late summer 1949 forced the government to devalue sterling on 18 September from $4.03 to $2.80.”

Page 516: “Eventually in January 1934 the Gold Standard Act of 1900 was replaced by the Gold Reserve Act. This raised the official price of gold from its old level of $20.67 to $35 per fine ounce—a substantial devaluation of 69.33 per cent.”

[220] Article: “Roosevelt’s Gold Program.” By Gary Richardson, Alejandro Komai, and Michael Gau. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The second phase of the Roosevelt administration’s gold policy began in October 1933 with the inauguration of the gold purchase plan.

This phase involved the deliberate devaluation of the dollar. The government did this by authorizing the Reconstruction Finance Corporation to buy gold at increasing prices. These purchases raised gold’s value in terms of dollars, conversely lowering the dollar’s value in terms of gold and in terms of foreign currencies, whose value in gold remained pegged at old prices.

The goal of these programs was to raise American prices of commodities like wheat and cotton, returning them to the level of 1926, before the beginning of the contraction. This reflation would counteract the deflation that had dragged the economy into the abyss. The reflation would relieve debtors, resuscitate banks, and revive businesses. The reflation would lower prices of American goods abroad, encouraging exports, and raise prices of foreign goods in the US, discouraging imports.

[221] Article: “A History of Sterling.” By Kit Dawnay. London Telegraph, October 8, 2001. <www.telegraph.co.uk>

“The pound was devalued by 30 per cent on September 18 1949. The enormous postwar balance of payments deficit was just too much for the UK. Lend lease and debt due American had taken its toll. Sterling’s weakness and decline then became glaring. National banks wanted dollars not pounds. … [T]he 1949 devaluation had helped Britain’s exports….”

[222] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

“The gold standard was also an international standard—determining the value of a country’s currency in terms of other countries’ currencies. Because adherents to the standard maintained a fixed price for gold, rates of exchange between currencies tied to gold were necessarily fixed.”

[223] Entry: “Exchange Rate.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

“An exchange rate is ‘fixed’ when countries use gold or another agreed-upon standard, and each currency is worth a specific measure of the metal or other standard.”

[224] Entry: “Gold Standard.” By Michael D. Bordo. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

“Because adherents to the standard maintained a fixed price for gold, rates of exchange between currencies tied to gold were necessarily fixed. For example, the United States fixed the price of gold at $20.67 per ounce; Britain fixed the price at £3 17s. 10.5d per ounce. The exchange rate between dollars and pounds—the ‘par exchange rate’—necessarily equaled $4.867 per pound.”

[225] Entry: “Exchange Rate.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

An exchange rate is “floating” when supply and demand or speculation sets exchange rates (conversion units). If a country imports large quantities of goods, the demand will push up the exchange rate for that country, making the imported goods more expensive to buyers in that country. As the goods become more expensive, demand drops, and that country’s money becomes cheaper in relation to the other countries’ money. Then the country’s good become cheaper to buyers abroad, demand rises, and exports from the country increase.

World trade now depends on a managed floating exchange system. Governments act to stabilize their countries’ exchange rates by limiting imports, stimulating exports, or devaluing currencies.

[226] Dataset: “Dollar–Pound Exchange Rate From 1791.” By Lawrence H. Officer. MeasuringWorth, 2018. <www.measuringworth.com>

[227] Article: “A Short History of the British Pound.” By Chris Parker. World Economic Forum, June 27, 2016. <www.weforum.org>

1717

The United Kingdom defined sterling’s value in terms of gold rather than silver for the first time. …

The United Kingdom suspended the gold standard in 1914 so it could support its war efforts. …

Winston Churchill returned sterling to the gold standard in 1925 at the pre-war rate of £4.86 to the dollar.

1931

Sterling came off the gold standard and the pound promptly dropped considerably.

[228] Book: A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day (3rd edition). By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 299: “An emergency meeting of the Privy Council … resolved that ‘the Bank of England should forbear issuing any cash,’ a situation confirmed by the ‘Bank Restriction Act’ of 3 May 1797. The restriction, then expected to be of very short duration, was in fact to last until 1 May 1821. A new era of inconvertible paper had arrived.”

Page 356: “In 1816 gold became at last legally recognized as the official standard of value for the pound, though it was not until the restoration of convertibility in 1821 that the domestic gold standard was in full operation.”

Page 395: “Intensified speculation against the pound in late summer 1949 forced the government to devalue sterling on 18 September from $4.03 to $2.80.”

Pages 446–447: “The Bretton Woods agreement of 1944 envisaged an idealized post-war world of convertible currencies, fixed exchange rates and free trade. … The inescapable decision facing the US authorities was taken on 15 August 1971 when the convertibility of the dollar at the fixed price of $35 per ounce of gold was ended.”

Page 469: “That Act [Coinage Act of 1792] officially adopted the dollar as the American unit of account…. [T]he dollar was officially to be bimetallist, being defined as equivalent to 371.25 grains of silver or 24.75 grains of gold.”

Page 488: “Priority in the use of the nation’s supply of gold and silver was given for government purposes, and the drain of specie from the banks led to the formal declaration of suspension by Congress at the end of December 1861.”

Page 496: “By the Coinage Act of 1873 … the USA was now virtually on the gold standard. … [T]he government felt it safe, by the Resumption Act of January 1875, to promise full redemption by 1 January 1879.”

Page 516: “Eventually in January 1934 the Gold Standard Act of 1900 was replaced by the Gold Reserve Act. This raised the official price of gold from its old level of $20.67 to $35 per fine ounce—a substantial devaluation of 69.33 per cent.”

[229] Book: A History of Money. By Glyn Davies. University of Wales Press, 2002.

Page 174: “Sterling was therefore much more widely used [in Medieval times] than simply within the domestic [English] economy, being a preferred silver currency over much of northern Europe, though playing very much a secondary role in international trade when compared with the gold florins of Florence or Ghent, or the ducats of Venice.”

Page 252:

The earliest extant English goldsmith’s receipt appeared some twenty-six years before the cheque and was issued by Laurence Hoare in 1633. A goldsmith’s receipt or note was evidence of ability to pay; of money in the bank. At first such receipts were issued to named customers who had made deposits of cash, and in time became negotiable just like endorsed bills of exchange. Then some ingenious goldsmith conceived the epoch-making notion of giving notes not only to those who had deposited metal, but also to those who came to borrow it, and so founded modern banking.

[230] Article: “Creation of the Bretton Woods System.” By Sandra Kollen Ghizoni. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

“A new international monetary system was forged by delegates from forty-four nations in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, in July 1944. … The countries agreed to keep their currencies fixed but adjustable (within a 1 percent band) to the dollar, and the dollar was fixed to gold at $35 an ounce.”

[231] Article: “The End of the Bretton Woods System (1972–81).” International Monetary Fund. Accessed December 9, 2017 at <www.imf.org>

By the early 1960s, the U.S. dollar’s fixed value against gold, under the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, was seen as overvalued. A sizable increase in domestic spending on President Lyndon Johnson’s Great Society programs and a rise in military spending caused by the Vietnam War gradually worsened the overvaluation of the dollar. …

The system dissolved between 1968 and 1973. In August 1971, U.S. President Richard Nixon announced the “temporary” suspension of the dollar’s convertibility into gold. While the dollar had struggled throughout most of the 1960s within the parity established at Bretton Woods, this crisis marked the breakdown of the system. An attempt to revive the fixed exchange rates failed, and by March 1973 the major currencies began to float against each other.

[232] Article: “The End of the Bretton Woods System (1972–81).” International Monetary Fund. Accessed December 9, 2017 at <www.imf.org>

An attempt to revive the fixed exchange rates failed, and by March 1973 the major currencies began to float against each other.

Since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system, IMF [International Monetary Fund] members have been free to choose any form of exchange arrangement they wish (except pegging their currency to gold): allowing the currency to float freely, pegging it to another currency or a basket of currencies, adopting the currency of another country, participating in a currency bloc, or forming part of a monetary union.

[233] Article: “Exchange Rate Regimes: Fix or Float?” By Mark Stone, Harald Anderson, and Romain Veyrune. International Monetary Fund Finance and Development, March 2008. <www.imf.org>

At one end of the spectrum are hard exchange rate pegs. These entail either the legally mandated use of another country’s currency (also known as full dollarization) or a legal mandate that requires the central bank to keep foreign assets at least equal to local currency in circulation and bank reserves (also known as a currency board). Panama, which has long used the U.S. dollar, is an example of full dollarization, and Hong Kong SAR operates a currency board.

Hard pegs usually go hand in hand with sound fiscal and structural policies and low inflation. They tend to remain in place for a long time, thus providing a higher degree of certainty for pricing international transactions. However, the central bank in a country with a hard exchange rate peg has no independent monetary policy because it has no exchange rate to adjust and its interest rates are tied to those of the anchor-currency country.

[234] Article: “Exchange Rate Regimes: Fix or Float?” By Mark Stone, Harald Anderson, and Romain Veyrune. International Monetary Fund Finance and Development, March 2008. <www.imf.org>

In the middle of the spectrum are soft exchange rate pegs—that is, currencies that maintain a stable value against an anchor currency or a composite of currencies. The exchange rate can be pegged to the anchor within a narrow (+1 or –1 percent) or a wide (up to +30 or –30 percent) range, and, in some cases, the peg moves up or down over time—usually depending on differences in inflation rates across countries. … Although soft pegs maintain a firm “nominal anchor” (that is, a nominal price or quantity that serves as a target for monetary policy) to settle inflation expectations, they allow for a limited degree of monetary policy flexibility to deal with shocks. However, soft pegs can be vulnerable to financial crises—which can lead to a large devaluation or even abandonment of the peg—and this type of regime tends not to be long lasting.

[235] Article: “Exchange Rate Regimes: Fix or Float?” By Mark Stone, Harald Anderson, and Romain Veyrune. International Monetary Fund Finance and Development, March 2008. <www.imf.org>

At the other end of the spectrum are floating exchange rate regimes. As the name implies, the floating exchange rate is mainly market determined. In countries that allow their exchange rates to float, the central banks intervene (through purchases or sales of foreign currency in exchange for local currency) mostly to limit short-term exchange rate fluctuations. However, in a few countries (for example, New Zealand, Sweden, Iceland, the United States, and those in the euro area), the central banks almost never intervene to manage the exchange rates.

Floating regimes offer countries the advantage of maintaining an independent monetary policy. In such countries, the foreign exchange and other financial markets must be deep enough to absorb shocks without large exchange rate changes. Also, financial instruments must be available to hedge the risks posed by a fluctuating exchange rate. Almost all advanced economies have floating regimes, as do most large emerging market countries.

[236] “Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2016.” International Monetary Fund, November 11, 2016. <www.imf.org>

Page 48: “Other managed arrangement—This category is a residual and is used when the exchange rate arrangement does not meet the criteria for any of the other categories. Arrangements characterized by frequent shifts in policies may fall into this category.”

[237] “Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2016.” International Monetary Fund, November 11, 2016. <www.imf.org>

Page 1: “In addition to the 189 IMF member countries, the report includes information on Hong Kong SAR (China) as well as Aruba and Curaçao and Sint Maarten (all in the Kingdom of the Netherlands).”

[238] Calculated with data from: “Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2016.” International Monetary Fund, November 11, 2016. <www.imf.org>

Pages 5–8:

Table 2. De Facto Classification of Exchange Rate Arrangements and Monetary Policy Frameworks, April 30, 2016

The system distinguished among four major categories: hard pegs (such as exchange arrangements with no separate legal tender and currency board arrangements); soft pegs (including conventional pegged arrangements, pegged exchange rates within horizontal bands, crawling pegs, stabilized arrangements, and crawl-like arrangements); floating regimes (such as floating and free floating); and a residual category, other managed. … Exchange rate arrangement (number of countries) … No separate legal tender (14) … Currency board (11) … Conventional peg (44) … Stabilized arrangement (18) … Crawling peg (3) … Crawl-like arrangement (10) … Pegged exchange rate within horizonal bands (1) … Other managed arrangement (20) … Floating (40) … Free floating (31)

CALCULATIONS:

  • 14 with no separate legal tender + 11 with currency board = 25 hard peg
  • 44 conventional peg + 1 pegged within horizonal bands + 3 crawling peg + 18 stabilized arrangements + 10 crawl-like arrangements = 76 soft peg
  • 40 floating + 31 free floating = 71 floating regimes

[239] “Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2016.” International Monetary Fund, November 11, 2016. <www.imf.org>

Page 8: “Table 3. Exchange Rate Arrangements, 2008–16 … (Percent of IMF members as of April 30) … 2016 … Hard peg [=] 13.0 … Soft peg[=] 39.6 … Floating [=] 37.0 … Residual [=] 10.4”

[240] Webpage: “Independence.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Accessed September 22, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

Beginning in 1775, the Continental Congress issued currency to finance the Revolutionary War. These notes, called Continentals, had no backing in gold or silver.

Continentals were backed by the “anticipation” of tax revenues. Easily counterfeited and without solid backing, the notes quickly became devalued, giving rise to the phrase “not worth a Continental.” This brief period marked the first time that U.S. currency’s value was derived solely from its purchasing power, as it is today.

[241] Webpage: “Money in Colonial Times.” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Accessed October 11, 2017 at <www.philadelphiafed.org>

In 1787, the Constitution gave Congress exclusive power to coin money, and in 1792, Congress passed its first coinage act, establishing a national mint in Philadelphia and outlining a coinage system.

The 1792 Coinage Act adopted the decimal system and combined Alexander Hamilton’s idea of a bimetallic standard with Thomas Jefferson’s proposal that the dollar be the standard unit of money. The denominations prescribed for silver coins were to be a half dime, dime, quarter dollar, half dollar, and dollar. Denominations for gold coins were to be a quarter eagle ($2.50), half eagle ($5), eagle ($10). Congress also provided for the coining of copper cents and half cents but did not give copper legal tender status; therefore, copper could be refused as payment.

[242] Article: “The Bank That Hamilton Built.” By Phil Davies. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis The Region, September 1, 2017. <www.minneapolisfed.org>

December 12, 1791, was a red-letter day in the financial history of the young United States. That day a bank unlike any previously seen in America opened for business in Carpenters’ Hall in Philadelphia, then the seat of the federal government. …

The intellectual architect of the bank—known today as the First Bank of the United States—was Alexander Hamilton, the founding father who most profoundly influenced the economic development of this country. As the Republic’s first Treasury secretary, Hamilton championed the idea of a national bank, proposing its establishment to Congress and convincing President George Washington—over the strenuous objections of Thomas Jefferson—that the bank would not violate the Constitution.

… After the Revolutionary War, the economy was in tatters: crushing war debt weighed down the federal government, and a shortage of sound currency and bank credit stifled commercial growth. Hamilton designed the First Bank to help the government get on its financial feet and to galvanize American commerce by providing currency and loans to businesses and individuals. The bank was a vital part of a national financial infrastructure that Hamilton created during his short but prodigious career, the template for today’s monetary economy based on a stable currency and access to credit.

[243] Article: “The Bank That Hamilton Built.” By Phil Davies. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis The Region, September 1, 2017. <www.minneapolisfed.org>

The new bank was a national bank, authorized by Congress to hold $10 million in capital—an astronomical sum at the time—and operate across state borders. And it was a quasi-public institution, owned mostly by businessmen and lawyers motivated by profit, but also intended to serve the public interest by improving the financial standing of the federal government and fostering economic growth.

[244] Article: “The Bank That Hamilton Built.” By Phil Davies. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis The Region, September 1, 2017. <www.minneapolisfed.org>

By December, it was ready to begin accepting deposits, making loans, selling U.S. Treasury bonds and issuing paper currency backed by gold and silver coin stored in its vaults. …

By aiding in revenue collection, lending to the Treasury and marketing government debt to private investors, the bank served as a financial bulwark for the federal government. And its operations invigorated markets by providing a sizable, trustworthy currency and extending credit to businesses.

[245] Article: “The Bank That Hamilton Built.” By Phil Davies. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis The Region, September 1, 2017. <www.minneapolisfed.org>

For all its successes, Hamilton’s bank could not overcome its political liabilities. When its charter came up for renewal in 1811, the Federalists were out of power; the Democratic-Republicans, who had remained hostile to the bank, now held the majority. Renewing Jefferson’s attack of 20 years earlier, they charged that the bank was unconstitutional, a perversion of the necessary-and-proper clause. Hamilton’s enemies had allies at many state banks, whose ranks had swelled to 90 since the First Bank’s founding. Coveting the bank’s federal government deposits, the directors of these banks—along with the representatives of state governments that owned bank stock—lobbied against recharter. The bank’s opponents also accused many of its directors of being Tories or monarchists, noting darkly that British investors held a large amount of its capital.

… Despite support from President James Madison and Treasury Secretary Albert Gallatin, Congress let the charter expire, and the bank closed its doors on March 3, 1811.

[246] Entry: “Bank of the United States.” Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

Despite its successes, the bank met political opposition that gathered force with partisan changes taking place in the country. In large part this opposition was based on the very restraints the bank imposed on private, state-chartered banks; this was also seen as an affront to states’ rights, and the bank’s federal charter was called unconstitutional. In 1811, when the 20-year charter expired, renewal was politically impossible. Its officers acknowledged reality and successfully sought a state charter in New York.

[247] Webpage: “What is the Fed: History.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

“The First Bank of the United States was chartered in 1791. A bill to re-charter the bank failed in 1811. Without a centralized banking and credit structure, state banks filled the vacuum, issuing a multitude of paper currencies of questionable value.”

[248] Book: A History of Currency in the United States. By A. Barton Hepburn. Macmillan Company, 1903.

Pages 88–90:

The second war with Great Britain began in 1812. The government found it necessary to borrow money and, as predicted by Hamilton, Gallatin, and Crawford, the state banks proved unequal to the emergency. Instead of the anticipated contraction of banking facilities after the liquidation of the First Bank, a rapid expansion had taken place, but much of the alleged bank capital was fictitious, a large number of banks having been organized upon capital represented by notes of hand of the subscribers.

… Adequate legal restrictions were wanting in most of the states, and notes were issued with ease and without regard to capital or specie [coin] holdings. In order to increase the volume as much as possible, since note-issues were their principal means of making loans and discounts, a mass of small denominations, some as low as six cents, were issued. Adding to this the stress of war and the consequent hoarding of specie, suspension of coin payments naturally followed. Most of the banks outside of New England suspended in August, 1814. The depreciation of Southern and Western bank-notes was most severe. At Baltimore, where notes from Southern banks were found in greatest abundance, the discount on some issues reached 23 per cent. In New York and Philadelphia 16 per cent was the maximum discount. …

The funds of the government were deposited in many of these banks throughout the country, and when suspension took place amounted to $9,000,000. Congress, in 1812, had been compelled to resort to an issue of “Treasury Notes” (the first since 1781) to cover short term loans. Five separate issues were authorized

during the war. …

The government did not succeed in disposing of its obligations at par. An official report shows that of the $80,000,000 of bonds and notes placed during the War of 1812, owing to the discounts thereon and the depreciated currency received in payment therefor, the Treasury actually obtained only $34,000,000.

In other words, had the Treasury been able to dispose of its notes and bonds at par in coin, and had its balances in the various state banks been available, a loan of $34,000,000 properly financed would probably have covered the expenses of the war, for which, ultimately, the people paid $80,000,000 and interest. Gallatin, in reviewing the period, expressed the opinion unequivocally that, had the Bank of the United States been rechartered, suspension of specie payments would have been avoided and so this loss, enormous for that period, would not have been incurred.

[249] Article: “The Bank That Hamilton Built.” By Phil Davies. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis The Region, September 1, 2017. <www.minneapolisfed.org>

“During the war the number of state banks exploded, and they stopped redeeming their notes for specie, contributing to high inflation.”

[250] Webpage: “What is the Fed: History.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

“Congress attempted to solve the country’s financial problems by chartering the Second Bank of the United States in 1816.”

[251] Article: “The Bank That Hamilton Built.” By Phil Davies. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis The Region, September 1, 2017. <www.minneapolisfed.org>

The Hamiltonian model of banking and monetary policy did not die with the First Bank, however. Out of the financial chaos that followed the War of 1812 rose a Second Bank of the United States. This federally chartered, well-capitalized institution was not as well managed as its predecessor, but in time it too exerted central-bank-like influence over the economy. During the war the number of state banks exploded, and they stopped redeeming their notes for specie, contributing to high inflation. Leveraging its large currency reserves, the Second Bank encouraged the redemption of those bank-notes for gold and silver, helping to shrink the money supply and stabilize prices.

[252] Webpage: “What is the Fed: History.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

“This second bank lasted until President Andrew Jackson declared it unconstitutional and vetoed its re-charter in 1836.”

[253] Webpage: “What Is the Fed: History.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

A period known as the Free Banking Era followed the demise of the Second Bank of the United States. Over the next quarter century, U.S. banking was a hodgepodge of state-chartered banks not subject to federal regulation. By 1860, nearly 8,000 state banks operated, each issuing its own paper notes. Some of the more marginal institutions were known as “wildcat banks” supposedly because they maintained offices in remote areas (“where the wildcats are”) in order to make it difficult for customers to redeem their notes for precious metals.

[254] Article: “The Free-Banking Era: A Lesson for Today?” By Daniel Sanches. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Economic Insights, 2016. <www.philadelphiafed.org>

“Free banking simply means that no charter or permission is needed from a government body to start a bank, unlike the current chartered banking system in the U.S. The free-banking laws specified that a state banking authority determined the general operating rules and minimum capital requirement, but no official approval was required to start a bank.”

[255] Webpage: “A History of Central Banking in the United States.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Accessed October 11, 2017 at <minneapolisfed.org>

Consequently, during the period from 1837 to the Civil War, commonly known as the free banking era, states passed “free bank laws,” which allowed banks to operate under a much less onerous charter. While banks were regulated, they were relatively free to enter the business by simply depositing government bonds with state auditors.

These bonds were the collateral backing the notes free banks issued. In addition, free banks were required to redeem their notes on demand in specie. As a result of the free banking laws, hundreds of new banks opened their doors, and free bank notes circulated around the country, often at a discount: The discount on a given bank note varied in part with the distance from the issuing bank and in part with the perceived soundness of the bank.

[256] Webpage: “History of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Education. Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.federalreserveeducation.org>

“During the Civil War, the National Banking Act of 1863 was passed, providing for nationally chartered banks, whose circulating notes had to be backed by U.S. government securities. An amendment to the act required taxation on state bank notes but not national bank notes, effectively creating a uniform currency for the nation.”

[257] Webpage: “A History of Central Banking in the United States.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Accessed October 11, 2017 at <minneapolisfed.org>

The outbreak of the Civil War and the need to finance it led again to a renewed interest in a national bank. But this time, with the lessons of the Second Bank, the designers took a different approach, modeled on the free banking system. In 1863, they established what is now known as the “national banking system.”

The new system allowed banks to choose between a national charter and a state charter. With a national charter, banks had to issue government-printed bills for their own notes, and the notes had to be backed by federal bonds, which helped fund the war effort. In 1865, state bank notes were taxed out of existence. Thus, in spite of all previous attempts, this was the first time a uniform national currency was established in the United States.

[259] Webpage: “A History of Central Banking in the United States.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Accessed October 11, 2017 at <minneapolisfed.org>

Panic! 1873, 1893, 1907

While the national banking system served its role in financing the war and establishing a uniform currency, it was fraught with at least one bank panic in every decade after the Civil War. A bank panic would often begin when depositors would learn that their bank was unable to meet withdrawal requests. This, in turn, caused a “run” on the bank, in which a large number of depositors attempted to pull out their money, causing an otherwise solvent bank to fail. Seeing this, depositors at other banks were led to withdraw their funds, causing a systemwide panic. In 1893, a bank panic coincided with the worst depression the United States had ever seen, and the economy stabilized only after the intervention of financial mogul J. P. Morgan. After another particularly bad panic and ensuing recession in 1907, bankers and the Congress decided it was time to reconsider a centralized national bank.

[260] Webpage: “What is The Fed: History.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

As the industrial economy expanded, the weaknesses of the nation’s decentralized banking system became more acute. Bank panics or “runs” occurred frequently. Many banks did not keep enough cash on hand to meet unusually heavy demand. Panics and runs often occurred when customers lost confidence in their banks after hearing news of failures of other banks. Fearful customers would rush to their banks to withdraw money, which often could not meet the sudden demand for cash. That sometimes created a contagion that triggered a succession of bank failures. A particularly severe panic took place in 1907 that abated only when a private individual, the financier J.P. Morgan, personally intervened to arrange emergency loans for financial institutions. This episode fueled a reform movement, which prompted Congress to establish the Federal Reserve System in 1913.

[261] Paper: “Do Economists Reach a Conclusion on Free-Banking Episodes?” By Ignacio Briones and Hugh Rockoff. Econ Journal Watch, August 2005. Pages 279–324.

<econjwatch.org>

Pages 303–304:

Another difference between Canada and the United States was the freedom of Canadian banks to establish branches, a freedom that was restricted in the United States. In the U.S. banks could not branch across states lines, and in some states, so called “unit-banking” states, banks were not allowed to establish branches even within the state that chartered the bank. As a result Canadian banks were larger than their American counterparts were, and the Canadian banks were better able to diversify the risks related to particular regions. The resulting difference in the stability of the two systems was dramatic. … The contrast between the stability of the Canadian system and the instability of the U.S. system, however, was present long before the Great Depression. By 1900 American reformers were drawing attention to the difference in stability and calling for reforms of the American system to make it more like the Canadian system.

[262] Paper: “The Banking Panics in the United States in the 1930s: Some Lessons for Today.” By Michael Bordo and John Landon-Lane. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, October 1, 2010. Pages 486–509. <academic.oup.com>

Page 495:

We have argued that the signature event in the US Great Contraction was the series of banking panics from 1930 to 1933. But this was nothing new in US financial history. From the early nineteenth century until 1914, the US had a banking panic every decade. There is a voluminous literature on US financial stability, and the lessons that come from that literature are that the high incidence of banking instability reflected two forces: unit banking and the absence of an effective lender of last resort.

(i) Unit Banking

Fear of the concentration of economic power largely explains why states generally prohibited branch banking and why since the demise of the Second Bank of the United States in 1836, there was until quite recently no interstate banking (White, 1983). Unit banks, because their portfolios were geographically constrained, were highly subject to local idiosyncratic shocks. Branching banks, especially those which extended across regions, can better diversify their portfolios and protect themselves against local/regional shocks.

A comparison between the experience of the US and Canadian banking systems makes the case (Bordo et al., 1996). The US until the 1920s has had predominantly unit banking and until very recently a prohibition on interstate banking. Canada since the late nineteenth century has had nationwide branch banking. Canada only adopted a central bank in 1934. The US established the Fed in 1914. Canada has had no banking panics since Confederation in 1867, the US has had nine. However, the Canadian chartered banks were always highly regulated and operated very much like a cartel under the guidance of the Canadian Bankers Association and the Department of Finance.

[263] Paper: “The U.S. Banking System From a Northern Exposure: Stability Versus Efficiency.” By Michael D. Bordo, Hugh Rockoff, and Angela Redish. Journal of Economic History, June 1994. Pages 325–341. <www.jstor.org>

Pages 325–326:

There is an immediate and important difference between the Canadian and United States banking systems. The Canadian experience has been one of considerable stability. There has been only one major bank failure since World War I, and there were no failures during the Great Depression. In contrast, the American system has been characterized by a number of periods of instability. Rates of bank failures were high in the 1920s, and of course the entire system collapsed during the 1930s. This difference … is typically, although not exclusively, attributed to differences in the structure of the banking systems. The Canadian banking system was a nationwide branch-banking system in which a small number of banks each had many branches, allowing a large amount of loan diversification. In contrast, the U.S. system of unit banking (or in some cases branching limited to a particular state) prevented banks from diversifying their portfolios.

[264] Article: “Why Was Canada Exempt From the Financial Crisis?” By Renee Haltom. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Econ Focus, 2013. Pages 22–25. <www.richmondfed.org>

Page 23:

According to the recent study by Calomiris and Haber, set out in their 2014 book Fragile By Design, united factions with an interest in keeping banks small succeeded in shooting down attempts at branching liberalization until the 1980s. They argued that the unique structure of the U.S. political system allows popular interests to sway policy more than in other countries. The U.S. Constitution gave all functions not explicitly handed to the federal government, such as regulatory policy, to the states. Interests needed only to win legislative fights at the local level, which was a far easier task than in today’s relatively more federalized system….

Small farmers opposed branching because it would allow banks to take credit elsewhere after a bad harvest. Small banks wanted protection from competition. And many others opposed any signs of growing power concentrated in any one institution—or bank. “Even in recent years, there was a feeling that local community banks were doing something really good and should be protected or encouraged in some way,” Rockoff says.

As the financial system evolved, branching was defeated at every turn.

[265] Article: “Riegle–Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994.” By Bill Medley. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History. Accessed October 18, 2017 at <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The Riegle–Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994 removed many of the restrictions on opening bank branches across state lines. These restrictions were largely the result of the McFadden Act in 1927 and other laws that attempted to address long-standing concerns about the concentration of financial activity and worries that large banking organizations operating in multiple states could not be adequately supervised.

[266] Webpage: “History of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Education. Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.federalreserveeducation.org>

The Aldrich–Vreeland Act of 1908, passed as an immediate response to the panic of 1907, provided for emergency currency issue during crises. It also established the national Monetary Commission to search for a long-term solution to the nation’s banking and financial problems. Under the leadership of Senator Nelson Aldrich, the commission developed a banker-controlled plan. William Jennings Bryan and other progressives fiercely attacked the plan; they wanted a central bank under public, not banker, control.

[267] Webpage: “History of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Education. Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.federalreserveeducation.org>

The 1912 election of Democrat Woodrow Wilson killed the Republican Aldrich plan, but the stage was set for the emergence of a decentralized central bank.

1912: Woodrow Wilson as Financial Reformer

Though not personally knowledgeable about banking and financial issues, Woodrow Wilson solicited expert advice from Virginia Representative Carter Glass, soon to become the chairman of the House Committee on Banking and Finance, and from the Committee’s expert advisor, H. Parker Willis, formerly a professor of economics at Washington and Lee University. Throughout most of 1912, Glass and Willis labored over a central bank proposal, and by December 1912, they presented Wilson with what would become, with some modifications, the Federal Reserve Act.

1913: The Federal Reserve System Is Born

From December 1912 to December 1913, the Glass–Willis proposal was hotly debated, molded and reshaped. By December 23, 1913, when President Woodrow Wilson signed the Federal Reserve Act into law, it stood as a classic example of compromise—a decentralized central bank that balanced the competing interests of private banks and populist sentiment.

[268] Article: “Woodrow Wilson’s Legacy Gets Complicated.” By Jennifer Schuessler. New York Times, November 29, 2015. <www.nytimes.com>

“The irony here is that Wilson really is the architect of a lot of modern liberalism,” said Julian E. Zelizer, a professor of history and public affairs at Princeton. “The tradition that runs through F.D.R. to L.B.J. and Obama really starts with his administration.” …

“Going to the mat for Wilson should not be hard,” said David Greenberg, a historian at Rutgers University. “If your standards are liberal progressive values in general, Wilson deserves to be celebrated.”

[269] “Federal Reserve Act of 1913.” 63rd U.S. Congress. Signed into law by Woodrow Wilson on December 23, 1913. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Section 18. Refunding Bonds

1. Application to Sell Bonds Securing Circulation

After two years from the passage of this Act, and at any time during a period of twenty years thereafter, any member bank desiring to retire the whole or any part of its circulating notes, may file with the Treasurer of the United States an application to sell for its account, at par and accrued interest, United States bonds securing circulation to be retired.

[270] Article: “Federal Reserve Bank Notes.” U.S. Department of the Treasury, Bureau of Engraving and Printing, Historical Resource Center. Last updated April 2013. <www.moneyfactory.gov>

“One of the primary purposes of the Federal Reserve System, established in late 1913, was to eliminate the system of National Bank Notes and to replace it with a centrally controlled system of Federal Reserve Notes.”

[271] Book: Paine’s Analysis of the Federal Reserve Act and Cognate Statutes. By Willis Seaver Paine. Bankers Publishing Company, 1917.

Page 147: “The banking sentiment of the country for some time has been in favor of the early retirement of as much of the National circulation as practicable.”

[272] Article: “McFadden Act of 1927.” By Gary Richardson, Daniel Park, Alejandro Komai, and Michael Gou. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The Federal Reserve earned acclaim for America’s economic performance during the Roaring Twenties. The Federal Reserve’s success led to the McFadden Act, which President Calvin Coolidge signed on February 25, 1927.

By the mid-1920s, bankers, businessmen, and politicians concurred that the Federal Reserve had accomplished the goals set forth at its founding. Since the System began operations, economic growth had been rapid. Interest rates had been stable. Financial crises had been contained. Recessions had been short. Recoveries had been rapid. Gold reserves had risen. The Federal Reserve Note (what we now call the dollar, but which in 1914 was one of many different dollars) had become one of the world’s leading currencies. Banks in the United States had become increasingly profitable and internationally prominent. The world economy, in contrast, had experienced a decade of doldrums following the First World War. …

… The original charters of the twelve Federal Reserve District Banks were set to expire in 1934, twenty years after the banks began operations. … To alleviate uncertainty, Congress not only rechartered the Federal Reserve Banks seven years early, but it also rechartered them into perpetuity.

As it turned out, if Congress had waited to renew the Federal Reserve’s charters, the debate over renewal would have occurred during the Great Depression. The decision may have been different, and the Federal Reserve as we know it today may not exist.

[273] Entry: “Great Depression.” By Robert J. Samuelson. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

“The start of the depression is usually dated to the spectacular stock market crash of 1929.”

[274] Webpage: “What Is the FOMC and When Does It Meet?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated August 17, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is the monetary policymaking body of the Federal Reserve System. The FOMC is composed of 12 members—the seven members of the Board of Governors and five of the 12 Reserve Bank presidents. The Board chair serves as the Chair of the FOMC; the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is a permanent member of the Committee and serves as the Vice Chairman of the Committee. The presidents of the other Reserve Banks fill the remaining four voting positions on the FOMC on a rotating basis. All of the Reserve Bank presidents, including those who are not voting members, attend FOMC meetings, participate in the discussions, and contribute to the assessment of the economy and policy options.

[275] Webpage: “What is The Fed: History.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Accessed September 25, 2017 at <www.frbsf.org>

Since the creation of the Federal Reserve, other pieces of legislation have shaped the structure and operation of the nation’s central bank. Following the Great Depression, Congress passed the Banking Act of 1935, which established the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) as the Fed’s monetary policymaking body. The Federal Reserve Reform Act of 1977 was enacted during a period of surging inflation. It explicitly set price stability as a national policy goal for the first time. The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act, approved in 1978 and known informally as the Humphrey–Hawkins Act, established full employment as a second goal of monetary policy and required the Fed to report to Congress on its policy twice a year. Most recently, following the severe financial crisis of 2007–08, Congress passed the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010. The law, known as the Dodd–Frank Act, affects the Fed in many ways. It changes the Fed’s governance, increases its transparency, expands its regulatory responsibilities, and transfers most Fed consumer protection responsibilities to a new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau.

[276] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 10–11:

The Board of Governors … is the governing body of the Federal Reserve System. It is run by seven members, or “governors”…. The Board of Governors guides the operation of the Federal Reserve System to promote the goals and fulfill the responsibilities given to the Federal Reserve by the Federal Reserve Act. …

The Board oversees the operations of the 12 Reserve Banks and shares with them the responsibility for supervising and regulating certain financial institutions and activities…. The Board also provides general guidance, direction, and oversight when the Reserve Banks lend to depository institutions and when the Reserve Banks provide financial services to depository institutions and the federal government. The Board also has broad oversight responsibility for the operations and activities of the Federal Reserve Banks…. This authority includes oversight of the Reserve Banks’ services to depository institutions, and to the U.S. Treasury, and of the Reserve Banks’ examination and supervision of various financial institutions. As part of this oversight, the Board reviews and approves the budgets of each of the Reserve Banks.

[277] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 6, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 6:

Reserve Bank activities serve primarily three audiences—bankers, the U.S. Treasury, and the public:

• Federal Reserve Banks are often called the “bankers’ banks” because they provide services to commercial banks similar to the services that commercial banks provide for their customers. Federal Reserve Banks distribute currency and coin to banks, lend money to banks, and process electronic payments. …

• Reserve Banks also serve as fiscal agents for the U.S. government. They maintain accounts for the U.S. Treasury, process government checks and conduct government securities auctions.

• Finally, Reserve Banks conduct research on the regional, national, and international economies; prepare Reserve Bank presidents for their participation on the FOMC; and distribute information about the economy through publications, speeches, educational workshops, and websites.

[278] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 14:

In its role providing key financial services, the Reserve Bank acts, essentially, as a financial institution for the banks, thrifts, and credit unions in its District—that is, each Reserve Bank acts as a “bank for banks.” In that capacity, it offers (and charges for) services to these depository institutions similar to those that ordinary banks provide their individual and business customers: the equivalent of checking accounts; loans; coin and currency; safekeeping services; and payment services (such as the processing of checks and the making of recurring and nonrecurring small- and large-dollar payments) that help banks, and ultimately their customers, buy and sell goods, services, and securities.

[279] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 9: “Three key Federal Reserve entities—the Federal Reserve Board of Governors (Board of Governors), the Federal Reserve Banks (Reserve Banks), and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)—make decisions that help promote the health of the U.S. economy and the stability of the U.S. financial system.”

Page 15:

The FOMC is the body of the Federal Reserve System that sets national monetary policy (figure 2.4). The FOMC makes all decisions regarding the conduct of open market operations, which affect the federal funds rate (the rate at which depository institutions lend to each other), the size and composition of the Federal Reserve’s asset holdings, and communications with the public about the likely future course of monetary policy.

[280] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 10–11:

The Board of Governors—located in Washington, D.C.—is the governing body of the Federal Reserve System. It is run by seven members, or “governors”…. The Board of Governors guides the operation of the Federal Reserve System to promote the goals and fulfill the responsibilities given to the Federal Reserve by the Federal Reserve Act. …

The Board oversees the operations of the 12 Reserve Banks and shares with them the responsibility for supervising and regulating certain financial institutions and activities…. The Board also provides general guidance, direction, and oversight when the Reserve Banks lend to depository institutions and when the Reserve Banks provide financial services to depository institutions and the federal government. The Board also has broad oversight responsibility for the operations and activities of the Federal Reserve Banks…. This authority includes oversight of the Reserve Banks’ services to depository institutions, and to the U.S. Treasury, and of the Reserve Banks’ examination and supervision of various financial institutions. As part of this oversight, the Board reviews and approves the budgets of each of the Reserve Banks.

[281] Webpage: “Who Are the Members of the Federal Reserve Board, and How Are They Selected?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated January 11, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“By law, the appointments [to the Board of Governors] must yield a ‘fair representation of the financial, agricultural, industrial, and commercial interests and geographical divisions of the country,’ and no two Governors may come from the same Federal Reserve District.”

[282] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed March 6, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 5:

Heading the Board of Governors are a Chairman and Vice Chairman, who are Governors whom the president of the United States appoints to serve four-year terms. The current Chairman of the Board of Governors is Jerome H. Powell. This is a highly visible position.

The Chairman reports twice a year to Congress on the Fed’s monetary policy objectives, testifies before Congress on numerous other issues, and meets periodically with the secretary of the Treasury.

[283] Webpage: “Who Are the Members of the Federal Reserve Board, and How Are They Selected?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated January 11, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“The Chair serves as public spokesperson and representative of the Board and manager of the Board’s staff. The Chair also presides at Board meetings.”

[284] Webpage: “Federal Reserve Banks.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Accessed August 23, 2018 at <www.richmondfed.org>

“[T]he nation has been divided into twelve Federal Reserve Districts, with Banks in Boston, New York, Philadelphia, Cleveland, Richmond, Atlanta, Chicago, St. Louis, Minneapolis, Kansas City, Dallas, and San Francisco. Twenty-five Branches of these Banks serve particular areas within each District.”

[285] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 12–13:

The 12 Federal Reserve Banks and their 24 Branches are the operating arms of the Federal Reserve System. Each Reserve Bank operates within its own particular geographic area, or district, of the United States. …

The boards of directors of the Reserve Banks represent a cross-section of banking, commercial, agricultural, and industrial interests. Six of the nine members of each board of directors are chosen to represent the public interest; those six board directors nominate their Bank’s president.

Federal Reserve member banks elect three Class A directors and three Class B directors. Class A directors represent District member banks. Class B directors represent the public. Federal Reserve Board of Governors appoints three Class C directors. Class C directors represent the public. Chair and deputy chair are designated by the Board of Governors from among Class C directors. Reserve Bank presidents are nominated by Class B and C directors and approved by the Board of Governors. …

As set forth in the Federal Reserve Act, each Reserve Bank is subject to “the supervision and control of a board of directors.” … Reserve Bank boards are responsible for overseeing their Bank’s administration and governance, reviewing the Bank’s budget and overall performance, overseeing the Bank’s audit process, and developing broad strategic goals and directions. …

Each year, the Board of Governors designates one chair and one deputy chair for each Reserve Bank board from among its Class C directors. The Federal Reserve Act requires that the chair of a Reserve Bank’s board be a person of “tested banking experience,” a term which has been interpreted as requiring familiarity with banking or financial services.

Each Reserve Bank board delegates responsibility for day-to-day operations to the president of that Reserve Bank and his or her staff. Reserve Bank presidents act as chief executive officers of their respective Banks and also serve, in rotation, as voting members of the FOMC. Presidents are nominated by a Bank’s Class B and C directors and approved by the Board of Governors for five-year terms.

[286] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 10:

Each Reserve Bank has its own board of directors, which oversees the Bank’s activities. These directors contribute local business experience, community involvement, and leadership and reflect the diverse interests of each District. Each board had nine members. Six of the directors are elected by member commercial banks. Three of the directors are appointed by the Board of Governors. From among these three, the Board of Governors selects a chairman and a deputy chairman of the given Bank’s board.

[287] Webpage: “Federal Reserve System.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Accessed August 23, 2018 at <www.richmondfed.org>

What Institutions Are Members of the Federal Reserve System, and What Does Membership Entail?

The nation’s commercial banks can be divided into three types according to which governmental body charters them and whether or not they are members of the Federal Reserve System. Those chartered by the federal government (through the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency in the Department of the Treasury) are national banks; by law, they are members of the Federal Reserve System. Banks chartered by the states are divided into those that are members of the Federal Reserve System (state member banks) and those that are not (state nonmember banks). State banks are not required to join the Federal Reserve System, but they may elect to become members if they meet the standards set by the Board of Governors. …

… Member banks receive a 6 percent dividend annually on their stock, as specified by law, and vote for the Class A and Class B directors of the Reserve Bank.

[288] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 6, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 6:

Reserve Bank activities serve primarily three audiences—bankers, the U.S. Treasury, and the public:

• Federal Reserve Banks are often called the “bankers’ banks” because they provide services to commercial banks similar to the services that commercial banks provide for their customers. Federal Reserve Banks distribute currency and coin to banks, lend money to banks, and process electronic payments. …

• Reserve Banks also serve as fiscal agents for the U.S. government. They maintain accounts for the U.S. Treasury, process government checks and conduct government securities auctions.

• Finally, Reserve Banks conduct research on the regional, national, and international economies; prepare Reserve Bank presidents for their participation on the FOMC; and distribute information about the economy through publications, speeches, educational workshops, and websites.

[289] Webpage: “The Structure and Functions of the Federal Reserve System.” Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Education. Accessed September 26, 2017 at <www.federalreserveeducation.org>

Approximately 38 percent of the 8,039 commercial banks in the United States are members of the Federal Reserve System. National banks must be members; state-chartered banks may join if they meet certain requirements. The member banks are stockholders of the Reserve Bank in their District and as such, are required to hold 3 percent of their capital as stock in their Reserve Banks. …

In addition to the approximately 3,000 member banks….

[290] Webpage: “What Is the FOMC and When Does It Meet?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated August 17, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is the monetary policymaking body of the Federal Reserve System. The FOMC is composed of 12 members—the seven members of the Board of Governors and five of the 12 Reserve Bank presidents. The Board chair serves as the Chair of the FOMC; the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is a permanent member of the Committee and serves as the Vice Chairman of the Committee. The presidents of the other Reserve Banks fill the remaining four voting positions on the FOMC on a rotating basis. All of the Reserve Bank presidents, including those who are not voting members, attend FOMC meetings, participate in the discussions, and contribute to the assessment of the economy and policy options.

[291] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Pages 11–12:

The FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] typically meets eight times a year in Washington, D.C. If economic conditions require additional meetings, the FOMC can and does meet more often.

The following occurs at each meeting:

• A senior official at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York discusses developments in the financial and foreign exchange markets, as well as activities of the New York Fed’s Trading Desk, where U.S. government securities are bought and sold.

• Staff from the Board of Governors then present their economic and financial forecasts.

• The Board’s Governors and all 12 Reserve Bank presidents—whether they are voting members that year or not—offer their views on the economic outlook.

Armed with this wealth of up-to-date national, international, and regional information, the FOMC discusses the monetary policy options that would best promote the economy’s sustainable growth. After all participants have deliberated the options, members vote on a policy that is given to the New York Fed’s Trading Desk. The policy directive informs the Desk of the Committee’s objective for “open market operations”—whether to maintain or alter the current policy. The Desk then buys or sells U.S. government securities on the open market to achieve this objective.

[292] Webpage: “A Day in the Life of the FOMC.” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, December 2008. <www.philadelphiafed.org>

At the end of this policy go-round, the Chair summarizes a proposal for action based on the Committee’s discussion, as well as a proposed statement to explain the policy decision. The Fed Governors and presidents then get a chance to question or comment on the Chair’s proposed approach. Once a motion for a decision is on the table, the Committee tries to come to a consensus through its deliberations. Although the final decision is most often one that all can support, there are times when some differences of opinion may remain, and voting members may dissent….

At the end of the policy discussion, all seven of the Fed Governors and the five voting Reserve Bank presidents cast a formal vote on the proposed decision and the wording of the statement.

[293] Webpage: “Is the Federal Reserve Accountable to Anyone?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

To further clear communication and foster transparency and accountability in monetary policy, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)—the body of the Federal Reserve System that sets national monetary policy—publishes a statement immediately following each of its eight annual FOMC meetings that describes the Committee’s views regarding the economic outlook and provides a rationale for its policy decision. Full minutes for each meeting are published three weeks after each FOMC meeting. Full verbatim transcripts of the FOMC meetings are made available with a five-year lag.

[294] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 10: “The Board of Governors—located in Washington, D.C.—is the governing body of the Federal Reserve System. It is run by seven members, or ‘governors,’ who are nominated by the President of the United States and confirmed in their positions by the U.S. Senate.”

[295] Webpage: “Who Owns the Federal Reserve?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Federal Reserve System is not “owned” by anyone. Although parts of the Federal Reserve System share some characteristics with private-sector entities, the Federal Reserve was established to serve the public interest. …

The Board of Governors in Washington, D.C. is an agency of the federal government. The Board—appointed by the President and confirmed by the Senate—provides general guidance for the Federal Reserve System and oversees the 12 Reserve Banks. The Board reports to and is directly accountable to the Congress but, unlike many other public agencies, it is not funded by congressional appropriations. …

Some observers mistakenly consider the Federal Reserve to be a private entity because the Reserve Banks are organized similarly to private corporations. For instance, each of the 12 Reserve Banks operates within its own particular geographic area, or District, of the United States, and each is separately incorporated and has its own board of directors. Commercial banks that are members of the Federal Reserve System hold stock in their District’s Reserve Bank. However, owning Reserve Bank stock is quite different from owning stock in a private company. The Reserve Banks are not operated for profit, and ownership of a certain amount of stock is, by law, a condition of membership in the System. In fact, the Reserve Banks are required by law to transfer net earnings to the U.S. Treasury, after providing for all necessary expenses of the Reserve Banks, legally required dividend payments, and maintaining a limited balance in a surplus fund.

[296] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 9: “The Federal Reserve Banks are not a part of the federal government, but they exist because an act of Congress. Their purpose is to serve the public. So is the Fed private or public? The answer is both. While the Board of Governors is an independent government agency, the Federal Reserve Banks are set up like private corporations.”

[297] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 10: “The Board of Governors—located in Washington, D.C.—is the governing body of the Federal Reserve System. It is run by seven members, or ‘governors,’ who are nominated by the President of the United States and confirmed in their positions by the U.S. Senate.”

[298] Webpage: “Who Are the Members of the Federal Reserve Board, and How Are They Selected?” Federal Reserve. Last updated January 11, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The full term of a Governor is 14 years; appointments are staggered so that one term expires on January 31 of each even-numbered year. A Governor who has served a full term may not be reappointed, but a Governor who was appointed to complete the balance of an unexpired term may be reappointed to a full 14-year term.

Once appointed, Governors may not be removed from office for their policy views. The lengthy terms and staggered appointments are intended to contribute to the insulation of the Board—and the Federal Reserve System as a whole—from day-to-day political pressures to which it might otherwise be subject.

[299] U.S. Code Title 12, Chapter 3, Subchapter II, Section 242: “Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Qualifications and Terms of Office of Members.” Accessed August 24, 2018 at <www.law.cornell.edu>

Upon the expiration of the term of any appointive member of the Federal Reserve Board in office on August 23, 1935, the President shall fix the term of the successor to such member at not to exceed fourteen years, as designated by the President at the time of nomination, but in such manner as to provide for the expiration of the term of not more than one member in any two-year period, and thereafter each member shall hold office for a term of fourteen years from the expiration of the term of his predecessor, unless sooner removed for cause by the President.

[300] Webpage: “Who Are the Members of the Federal Reserve Board, and How Are They Selected?” Federal Reserve. Last updated January 11, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Once appointed, Governors may not be removed from office for their policy views. The lengthy terms and staggered appointments are intended to contribute to the insulation of the Board—and the Federal Reserve System as a whole—from day-to-day political pressures to which it might otherwise be subject.”

[301] U.S. Code Title 12, Chapter 3, Subchapter II, Section 242: “Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Qualifications and Terms of Office of Members.” Accessed August 24, 2018 at <www.law.cornell.edu>

Upon the expiration of the term of any appointive member of the Federal Reserve Board in office on August 23, 1935, the President shall fix the term of the successor to such member at not to exceed fourteen years, as designated by the President at the time of nomination, but in such manner as to provide for the expiration of the term of not more than one member in any two-year period, and thereafter each member shall hold office for a term of fourteen years from the expiration of the term of his predecessor, unless sooner removed for cause by the President.

[302] Article: “Could President Gingrich Fire Fed Chair Bernanke?” By Eric Black. MinnPost, November 18, 2011. <www.minnpost.com>

The Federal Reserve Act establishes both 14-year terms for members of the board and four-year terms for the chair and adds: “each member shall hold office for a term of fourteen years from the expiration of the term of his predecessor, unless sooner removed for cause by the President.”

It’s not clear what that “for cause” language might mean. It’s never been tested. It implies to me that the president is supposed to have some “cause” other than disagreement over monetary policy, although it’s not really clear, hasn’t been tested, and I almost can’t imagine a Fed chair fighting to stay in office if a president was trying to dump him. But bear in mind, the president doesn’t need to establish a “cause” to fire most of his appointees, and the language is probably intended to underscore that the Fed chair is different from, let’s say, a cabinet member.

[303] Article: “Fire Bernanke? Not So Fast, Mr. Gingrich” Wall Street Journal, December 15, 2011. <blogs.wsj.com>

“Usually, ‘for cause’ means one or more of dereliction of duty, moral turpitude, physical or mental incapacity, or similar basic failings that demonstrate an unfitness for the office. It does not include disagreements about policy decisions, because these types of ‘for cause’ limits on removal are intended to insulate the office-holder from retribution for unpopular policy decisions,” says Calvin Massey, a professor at Hastings College of the Law in San Francisco.

[304] Webpage: “Board Members.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Last updated February 21, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“A member who serves a full term may not be reappointed. A member who completes an unexpired portion of a term may be reappointed. All terms end on their statutory date regardless of the date on which the member is sworn into office.”

[305] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed March 6, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 5:

Heading the Board of Governors are a Chairman and Vice Chairman, who are Governors whom the president of the United States appoints to serve four-year terms. The current Chairman of the Board of Governors is Jerome H. Powell. This is a highly visible position.

The Chairman reports twice a year to Congress on the Fed’s monetary policy objectives, testifies before Congress on numerous other issues, and meets periodically with the secretary of the Treasury.

[306] Webpage: “Who Are the Members of the Federal Reserve Board, and How Are They Selected?” Federal Reserve. Last updated January 11, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“In addition to serving as members of the Board, the Chair and Vice Chairman of the Board serve terms of four years, and they may be reappointed to those roles and serve until their terms as Governors expire. The Chair serves as public spokesperson and representative of the Board and manager of the Board's staff. The Chair also presides at Board meetings.”

[307] Webpage: “Who Owns the Federal Reserve?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“[E]ach of the 12 Reserve Banks operates within its own particular geographic area, or District, of the United States, and each is separately incorporated….”

[308] Webpage: “Who Owns the Federal Reserve?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Some observers mistakenly consider the Federal Reserve to be a private entity because the Reserve Banks are organized similarly to private corporations. For instance, each of the 12 Reserve Banks operates within its own particular geographic area, or District, of the United States, and each is separately incorporated and has its own board of directors.”

[309] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 10:

Each Reserve Bank has its own board of directors, which oversees the Bank’s activities. These directors contribute local business experience, community involvement, and leadership and reflect the diverse interests of each District. Each board had nine members. Six of the directors are elected by member commercial banks. Three of the directors are appointed by the Board of Governors. From among these three, the Board of Governors selects a chairman and a deputy chairman of the given Bank’s board.

[310] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 12–13:

The boards of directors of the Reserve Banks represent a cross-section of banking, commercial, agricultural, and industrial interests. Six of the nine members of each board of directors are chosen to represent the public interest; those six board directors nominate their Bank’s president.

Federal Reserve member banks elect three Class A directors and three Class B directors. Class A directors represent District member banks. Class B directors represent the public. Federal Reserve Board of Governors appoints three Class C directors. Class C directors represent the public. Chair and deputy chair are designated by the Board of Governors from among Class C directors. Reserve Bank presidents are nominated by Class B and C directors and approved by the Board of Governors.

… Much like the board of directors of private corporations, Reserve Bank boards are responsible for overseeing their Bank’s administration and governance, reviewing the bank’s budget and overall performance, overseeing the Bank’s audit process, and developing broad strategic goals and directions. However, unlike private corporations, Reserve Banks are not operated in the interest of shareholders, but rather in the public interest.

Each year, the Board of Governors designates one chair and one deputy chair for each Reserve Bank board from among its Class C directors. The Federal Reserve Act requires that the chair of a Reserve Bank’s board be a person of ‘tested banking experience,’ a term which has been interpreted as requiring familiarity with banking or financial services.

[311] “Federal Reserve Act of 1913.” 63rd U.S. Congress. Signed into law by Woodrow Wilson on December 23, 1913. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Section 11. Powers of Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System shall be authorized and empowered: …

Suspension or removal of officers and directors of Reserve banks

(f) To suspend or remove any officer or director of any Federal reserve bank, the cause of such removal to be forthwith communicated in writing by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System to the removed officer or director and to said bank.

[312] “Federal Reserve Act of 1913.” 63rd U.S. Congress. Signed into law by Woodrow Wilson on December 23, 1913. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Section 11. Powers of Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System shall be authorized and empowered: …

Suspension or removal of officers and directors of Reserve banks

(f) To suspend or remove any officer or director of any Federal reserve bank, the cause of such removal to be forthwith communicated in writing by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System to the removed officer or director and to said bank.

[313] “Federal Reserve Act of 1913.” 63rd U.S. Congress. Signed into law by Woodrow Wilson on December 23, 1913. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Section 4. Federal Reserve Banks

4. General corporate powers

… the said Federal reserve bank shall … have power— …

Fifth. To appoint by its board of directors a president, vice presidents, and such officers and employees as are not otherwise provided for in this Act, to define their duties, require bonds for them and fix the penalty thereof, and to dismiss at pleasure such officers or employees.

[314] Webpage: “Frequently Asked Questions.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Accessed October 24, 2018 at <www.minneapolisfed.org>

Under the Federal Reserve Act, the president of a Federal Reserve Bank is the chief executive officer of the Bank. The president is responsible for all the Bank‘s activities, including monetary policy, bank supervision and regulation, and payments services. In addition, the president serves on the Federal Reserve’s chief monetary policymaking body, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). …

The process for selecting a Federal Reserve Bank president is set forth in the Federal Reserve Act. Subject to the approval of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, the president is appointed by the Reserve Bank's Class B and C directors (those directors who are not affiliated with a supervised entity). …

The president of a Federal Reserve Bank is appointed for a term of five years. The terms of all the presidents of the 12 District Banks run concurrently, ending on the last day of February of years numbered 6 and 1 (for example, 2001, 2006 and 2011). The appointment of a president who takes office after a term has begun ends upon the completion of that term. A president of a Reserve Bank may be reappointed after serving a full term or an incomplete term. Reserve Bank presidents are subject to mandatory retirement upon becoming 65 years of age. However, presidents initially appointed after age 55 can, at the option of the board of directors, be permitted to serve until attaining 10 years of service in the office or age 75, whichever comes first.

[315] Webpage: “Who Owns the Federal Reserve?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“The Federal Reserve derives its authority from the Congress, which created the System in 1913 with the enactment of the Federal Reserve Act. This central banking system has three important features: (1) a central governing board—the Federal Reserve Board of Governors; (2) a decentralized operating structure of 12 Federal Reserve Banks; and (3) a blend of public and private characteristics.”

[316] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 21: “What is monetary policy? It is the Federal Reserve’s actions, as a central bank, to achieve three goals specified by Congress: maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates in the United States.”

[317] Webpage: “Who Owns the Federal Reserve?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“In addition, though the Congress sets the goals for monetary policy, decisions of the Board—and the Fed’s monetary policy-setting body, the Federal Open Market Committee—about how to reach those goals do not require approval by the President or anyone else in the executive or legislative branches of government.”

[318] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 3:

Congress oversees the entire Federal Reserve System. And the Fed must work within the objectives established by Congress. Yet Congress gave the Federal Reserve the autonomy to carry out its responsibilities without political pressure. Each of the Fed’s three parts—the Board of Governors, the regional Reserve Banks, and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)—operates independently of the federal government to carry out the Fed’s core responsibilities.

[319] Webpage: “Who Owns the Federal Reserve?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Commercial banks that are members of the Federal Reserve System hold stock in their District’s Reserve Bank. However, owning Reserve Bank stock is quite different from owning stock in a private company. The Reserve Banks are not operated for profit, and ownership of a certain amount of stock is, by law, a condition of membership in the System.”

[320] Webpage: “The Structure and Functions of the Federal Reserve System.” Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Education. Accessed September 26, 2017 at <www.federalreserveeducation.org>

“All member banks hold stock in Reserve Banks and receive dividends. Unlike stockholders in a public company, banks cannot sell or trade their Fed stock.”

[321] Webpage: “Federal Reserve System.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Accessed August 23, 2018 at <www.richmondfed.org>

Member banks must subscribe to stock in their regional Federal Reserve Bank in an amount equal to 6 percent of their capital and surplus, half of which must be paid in while the other half is subject to call by the Board of Governors. The holding of this stock, however, does not carry with it the control and financial interest conveyed to holders of common stock in for-profit organizations. It is merely a legal obligation of Federal Reserve membership, and the stock may not be sold or pledged as collateral for loans. … Stock in Federal Reserve Banks is not available for purchase by individuals or entities other than member banks.

[322] Article: “Financing the Fed’s Balance Sheet: Implications for the Treasury.” By Larry D. Wall. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Notes From the Vault, December 2015. <www.frbatlanta.org>

Nationally chartered banks and state chartered banks that become members of the Federal Reserve System must subscribe to stock equal to 6 percent of that bank’s capital and surplus, and must pay in one-half of that amount (12 United States Code 209).4 … In return for this investment, the bank is entitled by law to dividends equal to 6 percent of its paid-in capital (12 USC 289), which are cumulative.

The 6 percent dividend rate paid on Federal Reserve stock was set at, and has been constant since, the founding of the Federal Reserve. However, recently Congress passed the Fixing America’s Surface Transportation Act, which reduces the dividend for banks with consolidated assets exceeding $10 billion to the smaller of the 10-year Treasury note rate or 6 percent.

[323] Article: “The Cost of Fed Membership.” By Helen Fessenden and Gary Richardson. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Brief, February 2016. <www.richmondfed.org>

Page 1: “[Dividends] have been central to the relationship between the Federal Reserve System and commercial banks since the Fed’s founding in 1913. … Under this arrangement, the Reserve Banks paid member banks a dividend amounting to 6 percent on the stock that the Federal Reserve Act required member banks to pay in to the reserve Bank in their district.”

[325] Public Law 114-94: “Fixing America’s Surface Transportation Act.” 114th U.S. Congress. Signed into law by Barack Obama on December 4, 2015. <www.gpo.gov>

Title XXXII, Subtitle B, Section 32203:

Dividends of Federal Reserve Banks

(a) IN GENERAL—Section 7(a)(1) of the Federal Reserve Act (12 15 U.S.C. 289(a)(1)) is amended—

(1) by amending subparagraph (A) to read as follows:

“(A) DIVIDEND AMOUNT.—After all necessary expenses of a Federal reserve bank have been paid or provided for, the stockholders of the bank shall be entitled to receive an annual dividend on paid-in capital stock of—

“(i) in the case of a stockholder with total consolidated assets of more than $10,000,000,000, the smaller of—

“(I) the rate equal to the high yield of the 10-year Treasury note auctioned at the last auction held prior to the payment of such dividend; and

“(II) 6 percent; and

“(ii) in the case of a stockholder with total consolidated assets of $10,000,000,000 or less, 6 percent.” …

(b) EFFECTIVE DATE—The amendments made by subsection (a) shall take effect on January 1, 2016.

[327] Report: “Federal Reserve: Oversight and Disclosure Issues.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, March 27, 2017. <fas.org>

Page 8:

The Fed is statutorily required to “annually make a full report of its operations” to Congress that includes a full account of open market operations and “publish once each week a statement showing the condition of each Federal Reserve bank and a consolidated statement for all Federal Reserve banks” showing in detail the system’s assets and liabilities.32 This Annual Report is made available to the public and includes votes taken on monetary and regulatory decisions, as well as a summary of major actions taken.33 The Fed is statutorily required to have its financial statements annually audited by an independent auditor.34

[328] Webpage: “Is the Federal Reserve Accountable to Anyone?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“To ensure financial accountability, the financial statements of the Federal Reserve Banks and the Board of Governors are audited annually by an independent, outside auditor.”

[329] Report: “Federal Reserve: Oversight and Disclosure Issues.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, March 27, 2017. <fas.org>

Page 8:

The Fed is statutorily required to “annually make a full report of its operations” to Congress that includes a full account of open market operations and “publish once each week a statement showing the condition of each Federal Reserve bank and a consolidated statement for all Federal Reserve banks” showing in detail the system’s assets and liabilities.32 This Annual Report is made available to the public and includes votes taken on monetary and regulatory decisions, as well as a summary of major actions taken.33 The Fed is statutorily required to have its financial statements annually audited by an independent auditor.34

[330] Webpage: “Is the Federal Reserve Accountable to Anyone?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

[T]he Government Accountability Office, as well as the Board’s Office of Inspector General, frequently audit many Federal Reserve activities. Weekly, the Board of Governors publishes the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. During the recent financial crisis, the Federal Reserve provided information about its lending programs on its public website and in a special monthly report to the Congress. The Board also regularly reports the results of supervisory stress tests of large banks.

[331] Report: “Federal Reserve: Oversight and Disclosure Issues.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, March 27, 2017. <fas.org>

Page 2 (of PDF): “GAO [Government Accountability Office] can currently audit Fed activities for waste, fraud, and abuse. Effectively, the remaining statutory restrictions prevent GAO from evaluating the economic merits of Fed policy decisions. H.R. 24 would remove these restrictions and require a GAO audit that would not be subject to remaining statutory restrictions.”

Page 2: “The Fed’s OIG [Office of Inspector General] ‘promotes integrity, economy, efficiency, and effectiveness; helps prevent and detect fraud, waste, and abuse; and strengthens the agencies’ accountability to Congress and the public’;9 it does not perform policy or economic evaluations.”

Page 3: “There is no group with monetary policy expertise tasked by Congress with evaluating the Fed’s actions. Congress could create specific oversight boards or bodies composed of outside experts that focus on the Federal Reserve. Congress could also rely on GAO audits for enhanced oversight. The congressional debate has focused on GAO audits….”

Page 4:

The Federal Banking Agency Audit Act of 1978 (31 U.S.C. §714) gave GAO authority to audit the Fed’s non-monetary policy functions, such as its regulatory duties and role in the payment system. It prohibited GAO from auditing Fed activities related to:

(1) transactions for or with a foreign central bank, government of a foreign country, or nonprivate international financing organization;

(2) deliberations, decisions, or actions on monetary policy matters, including discount window operations, reserves of member banks, securities credit, interest on deposits, and open market operations;

(3) transactions made under the direction of the Federal Open Market Committee; or

(4) a part of a discussion or communication among or between members of the Board and officers and employees of the Federal Reserve System related to clauses (1)–(3) of this subsection.18

[332] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 6:

The Federal Reserve is not funded by congressional appropriations. Its operations are financed primarily from the interest earned on the securities it owns—securities acquired in the course of the Federal Reserve’s open market operations. The fees received for priced services provided to depository institutions—such as check clearing, funds transfers, and automated clearinghouse operations—are another source of income; this income is used to cover the cost of those services. After payment of expenses and transfers to surplus (limited to an aggregate of $10 billion), all the net earnings of the Federal Reserve Banks are transferred to the U.S. Treasury.

[333] Press Release: “Federal Reserve Board Announces Reserve Bank Income and Expense Data and Transfers to the Treasury for 2017.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 10, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Net income for 2017 was derived primarily from $113.6 billion in interest income on securities acquired through open market operations (U.S. Treasury securities, federal agency and government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and GSE debt securities) and foreign currency gains of $1.9 billion that result from the daily revaluation of foreign currency denominated investments at current exchange rates.

[334] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 6: “After payment of expenses and transfers to surplus (limited to an aggregate of $10 billion), all the net earnings of the Federal Reserve Banks are transferred to the U.S. Treasury.”

[335] Webpage: “Who Owns the Federal Reserve?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 1, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“The Reserve Banks are not operated for profit…. In fact, the Reserve Banks are required by law to transfer net earnings to the U.S. Treasury, after providing for all necessary expenses of the Reserve Banks, legally required dividend payments, and maintaining a limited balance in a surplus fund.”

[336] Press Release: “Federal Reserve System Publishes Annual Financial Statements.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 23, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“The Reserve Banks provided for remittances to the U.S. Treasury of $80.6 billion in 2017.”

[337] Webpage: “Summary of House Resolution 24: Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2017.” U.S. House of Representatives, 115th Congress (2017–2018). Accessed July 24, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Massie, Thomas [R-KY] (Introduced 01/03/2017) …

Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2017

(Sec. 2) This bill directs the Government Accountability Office (GAO) to complete, within 12 months, an audit of the Federal Reserve Board and Federal Reserve banks.

In addition, the bill allows the GAO to audit the Federal Reserve Board and Federal Reserve banks with respect to: (1) international financial transactions; (2) deliberations, decisions, or actions on monetary policy matters; (3) transactions made under the direction of the Federal Open Market Committee; and (4) discussions or communications among Federal Reserve officers, board members, and employees regarding any of these matters.

[338] Webpage: “Structure of the Federal Reserve System: About the Federal Reserve System.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated March 3, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Federal Reserve System is the central bank of the United States.

It performs five general functions to promote the effective operation of the U.S. economy and, more generally, the public interest. The Federal Reserve:

• conducts the nation’s monetary policy to promote maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates in the U.S. economy.

• promotes the stability of the financial system and seeks to minimize and contain systemic risks through active monitoring and engagement in the U.S. and abroad.

• promotes the safety and soundness of individual financial institutions and monitors their impact on the financial system as a whole.

• fosters payment and settlement system safety and efficiency through services to the banking industry and the U.S. government that facilitate U.S. dollar transactions and payments.

promotes consumer protection and community development through consumer-focused supervision and examination, research and analysis of emerging consumer issues and trends, community economic development activities, and the administration of consumer laws and regulations.

[339] Webpage: “What Is the Purpose of the Federal Reserve System?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated November 3, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Today, the Federal Reserve’s responsibilities fall into four general areas.

• Conducting the nation’s monetary policy by influencing money and credit conditions in the economy in pursuit of full employment and stable prices.

• Supervising and regulating banks and other important financial institutions to ensure the safety and soundness of the nation’s banking and financial system and to protect the credit rights of consumers.

• Maintaining the stability of the financial system and containing systemic risk that may arise in financial markets.

• Providing certain financial services to the U.S. government, U.S. financial institutions, and foreign official institutions, and playing a major role in operating and overseeing the nation’s payments systems.

[340] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 21:

What is monetary policy? It is the Federal Reserve’s actions, as a central bank, to achieve three goals specified by Congress: maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates in the United States.

The Federal Reserve conducts the nation’s monetary policy by managing the level of short-term interest rates and influencing the availability and cost of credit in the economy. Monetary policy directly affects interest rates; it indirectly affects stock prices, wealth, and currency exchange rates.

[341] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 21: “Monetary policy directly affects interest rates; it indirectly affects stock prices, wealth, and currency exchange rates. Through these channels, monetary policy influences spending, investment, production, employment, and inflation in the United States. Effective monetary policy complements fiscal policy to support economic growth.”

[342] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 22:

Prior to the financial crisis that began in 2007, the Federal Reserve bought or sold securities issued or backed by the U.S. government in the open market on most business days in order to keep a key short-term money market interest rate, called the federal funds rate, at or near a target set by the Federal Open Market Committee, or FOMC. (The FOMC is the monetary policymaking arm of the Federal Reserve.) Changes in that target, and in investors’ expectations of what that target would be in the future, generated changes in a wide range of interest rates paid by borrowers and earned by savers.

[343] Article: “How the Fed Seeks to Influence Interest Rates.” By Charles Davidson. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economy Matters, July 11, 2017. <www.frbatlanta.org>

It mostly comes down to one number.

That number is the federal funds rate, the interest rate financial institutions charge one another for overnight loans made from balances held at Federal Reserve banks.

But when the Fed’s policy-setting Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) decides to adjust the fed funds rate, not all interest rates throughout the economy change instantaneously. Rather, monetary policy is “transmitted,” through various channels, to an array of very short-term interest rates and financial market prices. These changes, in turn, ripple through the financial system to influence rates on all kinds of loans to consumers and businesses.

[344] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 13: “After all participants have deliberated the options, members vote on a policy that is given to the New York Fed’s Trading Desk. The policy directive informs the Desk of the Committee’s objective for open market operations—whether to maintain or alter the current policy. The Desk then buys or sells U.S. government securities on the open market to achieve this objective.”

[345] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 15:

Expansionary Monetary Policy

Step: 1 When the Fed buys government securities through securities dealers in the bond market, it deposits the payment into the bank accounts of the banks, businesses, and individuals who sold the securities.

Step: 2 Those deposits become part of the funds commercial banks hold at the

Federal Reserve and thus part of the funds commercial banks have

available to lend.

Step: 3 Because banks want to lend money, to attract borrowers they decrease

interest rates, including the rate banks charge each other for overnight

loans (the federal funds rate). …

Open market purchases of government securities increase the amount of reserve funds that banks have available to lend, which puts downward pressure on the federal funds rate. Policymakers call this easing, or expansionary monetary policy. If the economy were a car and the FOMC its driver, expansionary policy would be like gently pushing on the accelerator—giving the economy a little more fuel.

[346] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 15:

Contractionary Monetary Policy

Step: 1 When the Fed sells government securities, buyers pay from their bank accounts, which decreases the amount of funds held in their bank accounts.

Step: 2 Banks then have less money available to lend.

Step: 3 When banks have less money to lend, the price of lending that money—the interest rate—goes up, and that includes the federal funds rate. …

Sales of government securities shrink the funds available to lend and tend to raise the federal funds rate. Policymakers call this tightening, or contractionary monetary policy. Again, if the economy were a car and the FOMC its driver, contractionary policy would be like lightly tapping on the brakes—not enough to stop the car, but rather to slow its momentum a bit.

[347] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 19:

Reserve requirements are the portions of deposits that banks must hold in cash, either in their vaults or on deposit at a Reserve Bank. A decrease in reserve requirements is expansionary because it increases the funds available in the banking system to lend to consumers and businesses. An increase in reserve requirements is contractionary because it reduces the funds available in the banking system to lend to consumers and businesses. The Board of Governors has sole authority over changes to reserve requirements. The Fed rarely changes reserve requirements.

[348] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 20:

Interest on Reserves is the newest and most frequently used tool given to the Fed by Congress after the Financial Crisis of 2007–2009. Interest on reserves is paid on excess reserves held at Reserve Banks. Remember that the Fed requires banks to hold a percentage of their deposits on reserve. In addition to these reserves banks often hold extra funds on reserve. The current policy of paying interest on reserves allows the Fed to use interest as a monetary policy tool to influence bank lending. For example, if the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] wanted to create a greater incentive for banks to lend their excess reserves, it could lower the interest rate it pays on excess reserves. Banks are more likely to lend money rather than hold it in reserve (so they can make more money) creating expansionary policy. In turn, if the FOMC wanted to create an incentive for banks to hold more excess reserves and decrease lending, the FOMC could increase the interest rate paid on reserves, which is contractionary policy.

[349] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 6, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 6:

Reserve Bank activities serve primarily three audiences—bankers, the U.S. Treasury, and the public:

• Federal Reserve Banks are often called the “bankers’ banks” because they provide services to commercial banks similar to the services that commercial banks provide for their customers. Federal Reserve Banks distribute currency and coin to banks, lend money to banks, and process electronic payments. …

• Reserve Banks also serve as fiscal agents for the U.S. government. They maintain accounts for the U.S. Treasury, process government checks and conduct government securities auctions.

• Finally, Reserve Banks conduct research on the regional, national, and international economies; prepare Reserve Bank presidents for their participation on the FOMC; and distribute information about the economy through publications, speeches, educational workshops, and websites.

[350] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 14:

The Reserve Banks carry out Federal Reserve core functions by:

1. supervising and examining state member banks (state-chartered banks that have chosen to become members of the Federal Reserve System), bank and thrift holding companies, and nonbank financial institutions that have been designated as systemically important under authority delegated to them by the Board;

2. lending to depository institutions to ensure liquidity in the financial system;

3. providing key financial services that undergird the nation’s payment system, including distributing the nation’s currency and coin to depository institutions, clearing checks, operating the FedWire and automated clearinghouse (ACH) systems, and serving as a bank for the U.S. Treasury; and

4. examining certain financial institutions to ensure and enforce compliance with federal consumer protection and fair lending laws, while also promoting local community development.

[351] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 12: “Each Reserve Bank gathers data and other information about the businesses and the needs of local communities in its region. That information is then factored into monetary policy decisions by the FOMC and other decisions made by the Board of Governors.”

[352] Webpage: “Interest Rates.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Accessed October 22, 2018 at <www.richmondfed.org>

By law, the Board of Directors of each Reserve Bank establishes the discount rate independently every fourteen days subject to review and determination by the Board of Governors.

Originally, each Reserve Bank set its discount rate to reflect the banking and credit conditions in its own District. Over the years, the transition from regional credit markets to a national credit market has gradually produced a national discount rate. As a result, the Federal Reserve maintains a uniform structure of discount rates across all Reserve Banks.

[353] Entry: “Federal Reserve System.” By Manuel H. Johnson. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed October 22, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

A second monetary policy tool available to the Federal Reserve is the discount rate, the interest rate the Fed charges on loans it makes to banks. By increasing or decreasing this rate, the Fed can discourage or encourage banks to borrow the funds it creates and, therefore, make more loans to the public. The board of governors (not the FOMC) sets the discount rate by majority vote. In deciding the rate, however, the board does consider the recommendations of the directors from the twelve regional reserve banks. …

In the early days after the Federal Reserve Act, changes in the discount rate were the principal means of expanding credit growth in the regions. Because each regional reserve bank set its own separate discount rate, there often was no single prevailing Federal Reserve interest rate. As financial markets became more integrated, however, borrowers took advantage of the uneven discount rates by borrowing from the region offering the lowest rate. The ability of private banks to arbitrage between regional reserve bank rates constantly frustrated any attempt by Washington to centrally manage credit growth. This arbitrage eventually forced a standardized policy on the discount rate and brought into question the need for a decentralized Federal Reserve System.

[354] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 15: “[E]very two weeks, the board of each Reserve Bank recommends discount rates (interest rates to be charged for loans to depository institutions made through that Bank’s discount window); these interest rate recommendations are subject to review and determination by the Board of Governors.”

[355] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 6, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 19:

The discount rate is the interest rate Reserve Banks charge commercial banks for short-term loans. Federal Reserve lending at the discount rate complements open market operations in achieving the target federal funds rate and serves as a backup source of liquidity for commercial banks. Lowering the discount rate is expansionary because the discount rate influences other interest rates. Lower rates encourage lending and spending by consumers and businesses. Likewise, raising the discount rate is contractionary because the discount rate influences other interest rates. Higher rates discourage lending and spending by consumers and businesses. Discount rate changes are made by Reserve Banks and the Board of Governors.

[356] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 21: “What is monetary policy? It is the Federal Reserve’s actions, as a central bank, to achieve three goals specified by Congress: maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates in the United States.”

[357] Article: “The Federal Reserve’s ‘Dual Mandate’: The Evolution of an Idea.” By Aaron Steelman. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Brief, December 2011. <www.richmondfed.org>

Page 2:

[I]n early 1975, Congress adopted Resolution 133 instructing the Federal Reserve to, among other things:

maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the economy’s long run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long term interest rates.7

In 1977, Congress amended the Federal Reserve Act to incorporate the provisions of Resolution 133….

[358] Webpage: “History of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Education. Accessed September 24, 2017 at <www.federalreserveeducation.org>

1913: The Federal Reserve System Is Born

… By December 23, 1913, when President Woodrow Wilson signed the Federal Reserve Act into law, it stood as a classic example of compromise—a decentralized central bank that balanced the competing interests of private banks and populist sentiment.

[359] Article: “Federal Reserve’s Role During WWI.” By Phil Davies. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The outbreak of war in Europe in August 1914 touched off a financial crisis. The stock market closed and banks faced runs by depositors. Meanwhile, the Federal Reserve Board and the twelve Reserve Banks were still getting organized. The crisis soon passed, but within months a new problem emerged. A large inflow of European gold to pay for US exports increased the money supply. The young Fed was powerless to offset the gold inflow or halt the resulting inflation. And once the nation entered the war, the Fed dedicated itself mainly to supporting the war effort. …

The Great War inflicted enormous human and economic costs on the combatants. …

Federal spending surged as the military mobilized. Outlays for troop training, weapons, and munitions increased fifteen-fold from 1916 to 1918. In addition, the Treasury lent generously to US allies. …

As a result of Fed lending at low interest rates, credit conditions eased throughout the domestic economy, which was thriving on increased exports to Europe. Extensive borrowing by businesses and households stimulated economic growth but also increased the money supply, fueling inflation. In this period, raising or lowering interest rates on loans to member banks was the Federal Reserve’s main tool for regulating credit and controlling inflation. Changes in the Federal Reserve “discount” rate in turn affected interest rates on commercial paper and other types of loans and securities.

However, Fed leaders did not take steps to raise interest rates to fight inflation. Congress created the Fed as an independent central bank to isolate it from political pressure, but during the war monetary policy was beholden to the needs of the Treasury.

[360] Entry: “Great Depression.” By Robert J. Samuelson. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

The impact of World War I. Wartime inflation, when the gold standard had been suspended, raised prices and inspired fears that gold stocks were inadequate to provide backing for enlarged money supplies at the new, higher price level. This was one reason that convertible currencies, such as the dollar and pound, were used as gold substitutes. The war weakened Britain, left Germany with massive reparations payments, and split the Austro-Hungarian Empire into many countries. These countries, plus Germany, depended on foreign loans (in convertible currencies) to pay for their imports. The arrangement was unstable because any withdrawal of short-term loans would force the borrowing countries to retrench, which could cripple world trade.

[361] Entry: “Great Depression.” By Robert J. Samuelson. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Accessed September 19, 2018 at <www.econlib.org>

The depression is best understood as the final chapter of the breakdown of the worldwide economic order. The breakdown started with World War I and ended in the thirties with the collapse of the gold standard. As the depression deepened, governments tried to protect their reserves of gold by keeping interest rates high and credit tight for too long. This had a devastating impact on credit, spending, and prices, and an ordinary business slump became a calamity. …

The impact of World War I. Wartime inflation, when the gold standard had been suspended, raised prices and inspired fears that gold stocks were inadequate to provide backing for enlarged money supplies at the new, higher price level. This was one reason that convertible currencies, such as the dollar and pound, were used as gold substitutes. The war weakened Britain, left Germany with massive reparations payments, and split the Austro-Hungarian Empire into many countries. These countries, plus Germany, depended on foreign loans (in convertible currencies) to pay for their imports. The arrangement was unstable because any withdrawal of short-term loans would force the borrowing countries to retrench, which could cripple world trade. …

The gold standard handcuffed governments around the world. The mere hint that a country might abandon gold prompted speculators and international depositors to change local money into gold or a convertible currency. Deposit withdrawals spread panic and squeezed lending. It was a global process that ultimately forced all governments off gold. In May 1931 there was a run against Creditanstalt, a large Austrian bank. The panic then shifted to Germany and, in late summer, to Britain, which left gold in September.

[362] Speech: “On Milton Friedman’s Ninetieth Birthday.” By Ben S. Bernanke. The Federal Reserve Board, November 8, 2002. <www.federalreserve.gov>

As everyone here knows, in their Monetary History Friedman and Schwartz made the case that the economic collapse of 1929–33 was the product of the nation’s monetary mechanism gone wrong. Contradicting the received wisdom at the time that they wrote, which held that money was a passive player in the events of the 1930s, Friedman and Schwartz argued that “the contraction is in fact a tragic testimonial to the importance of monetary forces [p. 300; all page references refer to Friedman and Schwartz, 1963].” …

For practical central bankers, among which I now count myself, Friedman and Schwartz’s analysis leaves many lessons. What I take from their work is the idea that monetary forces, particularly if unleashed in a destabilizing direction, can be extremely powerful. The best thing that central bankers can do for the world is to avoid such crises by providing the economy with, in Milton Friedman’s words, a “stable monetary background”—for example as reflected in low and stable inflation.

Let me end my talk by abusing slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve. I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression. You’re right, we did it. We’re very sorry. But thanks to you, we won’t do it again.

[363] Article: “The Great Depression.” By Gary Richardson. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

In 2002, Ben Bernanke, then a member of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, acknowledged publicly what economists have long believed. The Federal Reserve’s mistakes contributed to the “worst economic disaster in American history” (Bernanke 2002).

Bernanke, like other economic historians, characterized the Great Depression as a disaster because of its length, depth, and consequences. … The Depression was the longest and deepest downturn in the history of the United States and the modern industrial economy. …

By “did it,” Bernanke meant that the leaders of the Federal Reserve implemented policies that they thought were in the public interest. Unintentionally, some of their decisions hurt the economy. Other policies that would have helped were not adopted.

An example of the former is the Fed’s decision to raise interest rates in 1928 and 1929. The Fed did this in an attempt to limit speculation in securities markets. This action slowed economic activity in the United States. Because the international gold standard linked interest rates and monetary policies among participating nations, the Fed’s actions triggered recessions in nations around the globe. The Fed repeated this mistake when responding to the international financial crisis in the fall of 1931. …

An example of the latter is the Fed’s failure to act as a lender of last resort during the banking panics that began in the fall of 1930 and ended with the banking holiday in the winter of 1933. …

These differences of opinion contributed to the Federal Reserve’s most serious sin of omission: failure to stem the decline in the supply of money. From the fall of 1930 through the winter of 1933, the money supply fell by nearly 30 percent. The declining supply of funds reduced average prices by an equivalent amount. This deflation increased debt burdens; distorted economic decision-making; reduced consumption; increased unemployment; and forced banks, firms, and individuals into bankruptcy. …

The Federal Reserve could have prevented deflation by preventing the collapse of the banking system or by counteracting the collapse with an expansion of the monetary base, but it failed to do so….

[364] Article: “Federal Reserve’s Role During WWII.” By Gary Richardson. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

Financing the war was the focus of the Federal Reserve’s wartime mission. This mission differed from the mission of the System before and after the war. …

Plans for financing the war were devised by the Treasury and the Federal Reserve. These organizations met frequently to determine how to finance the war and organize machinery for marketing United States government securities. …

In sum, the Federal Reserve played important roles during World War II. The Fed helped to finance the war, fund our allies, embargo our enemies, stabilize the economy, and plan the postwar return to peacetime activities.

[365] Calculated with data from:

a) Book: Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970 (Part 1).” U.S. Census Bureau, September 1975. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 126: “Series D 1–10. Labor Force and Its Components: 1900 to 1947 [in Thousands of Persons 14 Years Old and Over. Annual Averages]”

b) Dataset: “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed August 8, 2018 at <data.bls.gov>

“Series Id: LNS14000000; Series Title: (Seas) Unemployment Rate, Seasonally Adjusted; Labor Force Status: Unemployment Rate; Type of Data: Percent or Rate; Age: 16 Years and Over; Years: 1948 to 2017”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[366] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed September 11, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 16: “The first part of the Fed’s dual mandate is price stability, which means that the economy is not experiencing high or variable inflation or deflation.”

[367] Webpage: “What Economic Goals Does the Federal Reserve Seek to Achieve Through Its Monetary Policy?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated August 19, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Prices are considered stable when consumers and businesses don’t have to worry about rising or falling prices when making plans, or when borrowing or lending for long periods. When prices are stable, long-term interest rates remain at moderate levels, so the goals of price stability and moderate long-term interest rates go together.”

[368] Article: “Stable Prices, Stable Economy: Keeping Inflation in Check Must Be No. 1 Goal of Monetary Policymakers.” By William Poole and David C. Wheelock. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, January 2008. <www.stlouisfed.org>

“Price stability” is usually interpreted to mean a low and stable rate of inflation maintained over an extended period of time. In our view, the ideal rate of inflation is zero, properly measured. Biases in price indexes imply that, in practice, price stability will likely be consistent with a small positive rate of measured inflation, say 0.5 to 1 percent, depending on the specific price index one looks at. Further, price stability does not mean that the price index is constant. Monetary policy could never eliminate every wiggle in the inflation rate; nor should policymakers try to do so.

Price stability means that inflation is sufficiently low and stable so as not to influence the economic decisions of households and firms. When inflation is low and reasonably stable, people do not waste resources attempting to protect themselves from inflation. They save and invest with confidence that the value of money will be stable over time.

[369] Calculated with data from the book: Handbook of Labor Statistics 1971. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1971.

Page 253: “Table 111. Consumer Price Index, U.S. City Average for All Items, 1800–1970 and for Selected Groups, and Purchasing Power of the Consumer Dollar, 1913–1970 (1967=100)”

NOTES:

  • The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics compiled the above-cited table using data from the Index of Prices Paid by Vermont Farmers for Family Living for 1800–1851, Consumer Price Index by Ethel D. Hoover for 1851–1890, and Cost of Living Index by Albert Rees for 1890–1912.
  • An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[370] Calculated with the dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[371] Calculated with the dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[372] Calculated with data from:

a) Book: Handbook of Labor Statistics 1971. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1971.

Page 253: “Table 111. Consumer Price Index, U.S. City Average for All Items, 1800–1970 and for Selected Groups, and Purchasing Power of the Consumer Dollar, 1913–1970 (1967=100)”

b) Dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[373] Speech: “What the Federal Reserve Is Doing to Promote a Stronger Job Market.” By Janet L. Yellen. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 31, 2014. <www.federalreserve.gov>

By keeping interest rates low, we are trying to make homes more affordable and revive the housing market. We are trying to make it cheaper for businesses to build, expand, and hire. We are trying to lower the costs of buying a car that can carry a worker to a new job and kids to school, and our policies are also spurring the revival of the auto industry. We are trying to help families afford things they need so that greater spending can drive job creation and even more spending, thereby strengthening the recovery.

When the Federal Reserve’s policies are effective, they improve the welfare of everyone who benefits from a stronger economy, most of all those who have been hit hardest by the recession and the slow recovery.

[374] Webpage: “How Does Monetary Policy Affect the U.S. Economy?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Last updated February 6, 2004. <www.frbsf.org>

Long-term interest rates reflect, in part, what people in financial markets expect the Fed to do in the future. For instance, if they think the Fed isn’t focused on containing inflation, they’ll be concerned that inflation might move up over the next few years. So they’ll add a risk premium to long-term rates, which will make them higher. In other words, the markets’ expectations about monetary policy tomorrow have a substantial impact on long-term interest rates today. …

Changes in real interest rates affect the public’s demand for goods and services mainly by altering borrowing costs, the availability of bank loans, the wealth of households, and foreign exchange rates.

For example, a decrease in real interest rates lowers the cost of borrowing; that leads businesses to increase investment spending, and it leads households to buy durable goods, such as autos and new homes.

In addition, lower real rates and a healthy economy may increase banks’ willingness to lend to businesses and households. This may increase spending, especially by smaller borrowers who have few sources of credit other than banks.

Lower real rates also make common stocks and other such investments more attractive than bonds and other debt instruments; as a result, common stock prices tend to rise. Households with stocks in their portfolios find that the value of their holdings is higher, and this increase in wealth makes them willing to spend more. Higher stock prices also make it more attractive for businesses to invest in plant and equipment by issuing stock.

In the short run, lower real interest rates in the U.S. also tend to reduce the foreign exchange value of the dollar, which lowers the prices of the U.S.-produced goods we sell abroad and raises the prices we pay for foreign-produced goods. This leads to higher aggregate spending on goods and services produced in the U.S.

The increase in aggregate demand for the economy’s output through these different channels leads firms to raise production and employment, which in turn increases business spending on capital goods even further by making greater demands on existing factory capacity. It also boosts consumption further because of the income gains that result from the higher level of economic output.

[375] Calculated with data from:

a) Report: “Federal Reserve Bulletin.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 1945. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Pages 483–490: “U.S. Government Security Yields and Prices.”

b) Report: “Supplement to Banking & Monetary Statistics: Money Rates and Securities Markets.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 1966. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Pages 68–73: “11. Bond Yields, By Type of Security. A. Annually and Monthly, 1941–63.”

c) Dataset: “10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Research Division. Accessed September 4, 2018 at <fred.stlouisfed.org>

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[376] Chart constructed with data from:

a) Report: “Federal Reserve Bulletin.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 1945. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Pages 483–490: “U.S. Government Security Yields and Prices.”

b) Report: “Supplement to Banking & Monetary Statistics: Money Rates and Securities Markets.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 1966. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Pages 68–73: “11. Bond Yields, By Type of Security. A. Annually and Monthly, 1941–63.”

c) Dataset: “10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Research Division. Accessed September 4, 2018 at <fred.stlouisfed.org>

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data is available upon request.

[377] Paper: “Measuring the Economy: A Primer on GDP and the National Income and Product Accounts.” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, December 2015. <www.bea.gov>

Page 1:

How fast is the economy growing? Is it speeding up or slowing down? How does the trade deficit affect economic growth? What’s happening to the pattern of spending on goods and services in the economy?

To answer these types of questions about the economy, economists and policymakers turn to the national income and product accounts (NIPAs) produced by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). … Featured in the NIPAs is gross domestic product (GDP), which measures the value of the goods and services produced by the U.S. economy in a given time period.

GDP is one of the most comprehensive and closely watched economic statistics: It is used by the White House and Congress to prepare the Federal budget, by the Federal Reserve to formulate monetary policy, by Wall Street as an indicator of economic activity, and by the business community to prepare forecasts of economic performance that provide the basis for production, investment, and employment planning.

Page 8: “…GDP—is defined as the market value of goods, services, and structures produced by the Nation’s economy during a given period less the value of the goods and services used up in production.”

[378] Book: Economics: Principles and Policy (12th edition). By William Baumol and Alan Blinder. South-Western Cengage Learning, 2011.

Page 491:

To sharpen the point, observe that real GDP is, by definition, the product of the total hours of work in the economy times the amount of output produced per hour—what we have just called labor productivity:

GDP = Hours of work × Output per hour = Hours worked × Labor productivity

For example, in the United States today, in round numbers, GDP is about $15 trillion and total hours of work per year are about 230 billion. Thus labor productivity is roughly $15 trillion/230 billion hours, or about $65 per hour.

[379] Article: “Gross Domestic Product: An Economy’s All.” By Tim Callen. International Monetary Fund Finance & Development. Updated July 29, 2017. <www.imf.org>

One thing people want to know about an economy is whether its total output of goods and services is growing or shrinking. But because GDP is collected at current, or nominal, prices, one cannot compare two periods without making adjustments for inflation. To determine “real” GDP, its nominal value must be adjusted to take into account price changes to allow us to see whether the value of output has gone up because more is being produced or simply because prices have increased. A statistical tool called the price deflator is used to adjust GDP from nominal to constant prices.

GDP is important because it gives information about the size of the economy and how an economy is performing. The growth rate of real GDP is often used as an indicator of the general health of the economy. In broad terms, an increase in real GDP is interpreted as a sign that the economy is doing well. When real GDP is growing strongly, employment is likely to be increasing as companies hire more workers for their factories and people have more money in their pockets. When GDP is shrinking, as it did in many countries during the recent global economic crisis, employment often declines. In some cases, GDP may be growing, but not fast enough to create a sufficient number of jobs for those seeking them. But real GDP growth does move in cycles over time. Economies are sometimes in periods of boom, and sometimes in periods of slow growth or even recession (with the latter often defined as two consecutive quarters during which output declines). In the United States, for example, there were six recessions of varying length and severity between 1950 and 2011. The National Bureau of Economic Research makes the call on the dates of U.S. business cycles.

[380] Calculated with data from:

a) Dataset: “What Was the U.S. GDP Then?” By Louis Johnston and Samuel H. Williamson. MeasuringWorth, 2018. <measuringworth.com>

b) Dataset: “Table 1.1.1 Percent Change From Preceding Period in Real Gross Domestic Product [Percent].” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Last revised August 29, 2018. <www.bea.gov>

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[381] Article: “Quantitative Easing Explained.” By Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, April 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 1: “QE [Quantitative Easing] is not a new approach; it was used by the Fed in the 1930s,5 the Bank of Japan in 2001,6 and more recently by the Bank of England.”

[382] Article: “Great Depression.” By Richard H. Pells and Christina D. Romer. Encyclopedia Britannica, 1998. <www.britannica.com>

Great Depression, worldwide economic downturn that began in 1929 and lasted until about 1939. It was the longest and most severe depression ever experienced by the industrialized Western world, sparking fundamental changes in economic institutions, macroeconomic policy, and economic theory.”

[383] Article: “Quantitative Easing: How Well Does This Tool Work?” by Stephen D. Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, 2017. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 9: “Quantitative easing (QE)—large-scale purchases of assets by central banks—led to a large increase in the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet during the global financial crisis (2007–2008) and in the long recovery from the 2008–2009 recession.”

[384] Report: “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, September 20, 2010. <www.nber.org>

“Contractions (recessions) start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. … Peak [=] December 2007 (IV) … Trough [=] June 2009 (II)”

[385] Webpage: “What Is the FOMC and When Does It Meet?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated August 17, 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is the monetary policymaking body of the Federal Reserve System. The FOMC is composed of 12 members—the seven members of the Board of Governors and five of the 12 Reserve Bank presidents. The Board chair serves as the Chair of the FOMC; the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is a permanent member of the Committee and serves as the Vice Chairman of the Committee. The presidents of the other Reserve Banks fill the remaining four voting positions on the FOMC on a rotating basis. All of the Reserve Bank presidents, including those who are not voting members, attend FOMC meetings, participate in the discussions, and contribute to the assessment of the economy and policy options.

[386] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 21–22:

The Federal Reserve conducts the nation’s monetary policy by managing the level of short-term interest rates and influencing the availability and cost of credit in the economy. …

… Prior to the financial crisis that began in 2007, the Federal Reserve bought or sold securities issued or backed by the U.S. government in the open market on most business days in order to keep a key short-term money market interest rate, called the federal funds rate, at or near a target set by the Federal Open Market Committee, or FOMC. (The FOMC is the monetary policymaking arm of the Federal Reserve.) Changes in that target, and in investors’ expectations of what that target would be in the future, generated changes in a wide range of interest rates paid by borrowers and earned by savers.

[387] Article: “How the Fed Seeks to Influence Interest Rates.” By Charles Davidson. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economy Matters, July 11, 2017. <www.frbatlanta.org>

It mostly comes down to one number.

That number is the federal funds rate, the interest rate financial institutions charge one another for overnight loans made from balances held at Federal Reserve banks.

But when the Fed’s policy-setting Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) decides to adjust the fed funds rate, not all interest rates throughout the economy change instantaneously. Rather, monetary policy is “transmitted,” through various channels, to an array of very short-term interest rates and financial market prices. These changes, in turn, ripple through the financial system to influence rates on all kinds of loans to consumers and businesses.

[388] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 13: “After all participants have deliberated the options, members vote on a policy that is given to the New York Fed’s Trading Desk. The policy directive informs the Desk of the Committee’s objective for open market operations—whether to maintain or alter the current policy. The Desk then buys or sells U.S. government securities on the open market to achieve this objective.”

[389] Webpage: “In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Accessed August 21, 2018 at <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 15:

Expansionary Monetary Policy

Step: 1 When the Fed buys government securities through securities dealers in the bond market, it deposits the payment into the bank accounts of the banks, businesses, and individuals who sold the securities.

Step: 2 Those deposits become part of the funds commercial banks hold at the

Federal Reserve and thus part of the funds commercial banks have

available to lend.

Step: 3 Because banks want to lend money, to attract borrowers they decrease

interest rates, including the rate banks charge each other for overnight

loans (the federal funds rate). …

Open market purchases of government securities increase the amount of reserve funds that banks have available to lend, which puts downward pressure on the federal funds rate. Policymakers call this easing, or expansionary monetary policy. If the economy were a car and the FOMC its driver, expansionary policy would be like gently pushing on the accelerator—giving the economy a little more fuel.

[390] Article: “The Great Recession and Its Aftermath.” By John Weinberg. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The period known as the Great Moderation came to an end when the decade-long expansion in U.S. housing market activity peaked in 2006 and residential construction began declining. In 2007, losses on mortgage-related financial assets began to cause strains in global financial markets, and in December 2007 the US economy entered a recession. … [I]n the fall of 2008, the economic contraction worsened, ultimately becoming deep enough and protracted enough to acquire the label “the Great Recession.” …

… Average home prices in the United States more than doubled between 1998 and 2006, the sharpest increase recorded in US history, and even larger gains were recorded in some regions. …

The expansion in the housing sector was accompanied by an expansion in home mortgage borrowing by US households. Mortgage debt of US households rose from 61 percent of GDP in 1998 to 97 percent in 2006.

After home prices peaked in the beginning of 2007, according to the Federal Housing Finance Agency House Price Index, the extent to which prices might eventually fall became a significant question for the pricing of mortgage-related securities because large declines in home prices were viewed as likely to lead to an increase in mortgage defaults and higher losses to holders of such securities. … Ultimately, home prices fell by over a fifth on average across the nation from the first quarter of 2007 to the second quarter of 2011. This decline in home prices helped to spark the financial crisis of 2007–08, as financial market participants faced considerable uncertainty about the incidence of losses on mortgage-related assets.

[391] “The Financial Crisis Inquiry Report.” Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, January 2011. <www.gpo.gov>

Page 215:

For 2007, the National Association of Realtors announced that the number of sales of existing homes had experienced the sharpest fall in 25 years. That year, home prices declined 9%. In 2008, they would drop a stunning 17%. Overall, by the end of 2009, prices would drop 28% from their peak in 2006. …

Mortgages in serious delinquency, defined as those 90 or more days past due or in foreclosure, had hovered around 1% during the early part of the decade, jumped in 2006, and kept climbing. By the end of 2009, 9.7% of mortgage loans were seriously delinquent.

Page 226:

Through 2007 and into 2008, as the rating agencies downgraded mortgage-backed securities and CDOs [collateralized debt obligations], and investors began to panic, market prices for these securities plunged. Both the direct losses as well as the market wide contagion and panic that ensued would lead to the failure or near failure of many large financial firms across the system. The drop in market prices for mortgage-related securities reflected the higher probability that the underlying mortgages would actually default (meaning that less cash would flow to the investors) as well as the more generalized fear among investors that this market had become illiquid. Investors valued liquidity because they wanted the assurance that they could sell securities quickly to raise cash if necessary. Potential investors worried they might get stuck holding these securities as market participants looked to limit their exposure to the collapsing mortgage market.

Pages 227–228:

The large drop in market prices of the mortgage securities had large spillover effects to the financial sector, for a number of reasons. For example … when the prices of mortgage-backed securities and CDOs fell, many of the holders of those securities marked down the value of their holdings—before they had experienced any actual losses. In addition, rather than spreading the risks of losses among many investors, the securitization market had concentrated them. …

… A set of large, systemically important firms with significant holdings or exposure to these securities would be found to be holding very little capital to protect against potential losses. And most of those companies would turn out to be considered by the authorities too big to fail in the midst of a financial crisis.

Page 255:

When the mortgage market collapsed and financial firms began to abandon the commercial paper and repo lending markets, some institutions depending on them for funding their operations failed or, later in the crisis, had to be rescued. These markets and other interconnections created contagion, as the crisis spread even to markets and firms that had little or no direct exposure to the mortgage market.

[392] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

For almost a year and a half the global financial system has been under extraordinary stress—stress that has now decisively spilled over to the global economy more broadly. The proximate cause of the crisis was the turn of the housing cycle in the United States and the associated rise in delinquencies on subprime mortgages, which imposed substantial losses on many financial institutions and shook investor confidence in credit markets. However, although the subprime debacle triggered the crisis, the developments in the U.S. mortgage market were only one aspect of a much larger and more encompassing credit boom whose impact transcended the mortgage market to affect many other forms of credit. Aspects of this broader credit boom included widespread declines in underwriting standards, breakdowns in lending oversight by investors and rating agencies, increased reliance on complex and opaque credit instruments that proved fragile under stress, and unusually low compensation for risk-taking.

The abrupt end of the credit boom has had widespread financial and economic ramifications. Financial institutions have seen their capital depleted by losses and write-downs and their balance sheets clogged by complex credit products and other illiquid assets of uncertain value. Rising credit risks and intense risk aversion have pushed credit spreads to unprecedented levels, and markets for securitized assets, except for mortgage securities with government guarantees, have shut down. Heightened systemic risks, falling asset values, and tightening credit have in turn taken a heavy toll on business and consumer confidence and precipitated a sharp slowing in global economic activity. The damage, in terms of lost output, lost jobs, and lost wealth, is already substantial.

[393] Report: “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, September 20, 2010. <www.nber.org>

“Contractions (recessions) start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. … Peak [=] December 2007 (IV) … Trough [=] June 2009 (II)”

[394] Report: “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, September 20, 2010. <www.nber.org>

“Contractions (recessions) start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. … Peak [=] December 2007 (IV) … Trough [=] June 2009 (II)”

[395] Article: “Quantitative Easing Explained.” By Lowell R. Ricketts. Economic Education Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, April 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 1:

In late 2008, in response to rapidly deteriorating economic and financial conditions, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) pushed the federal funds rate target1 close to zero. As conditions worsened, the Fed turned to nontraditional policies to bolster financial market conditions. Such policies include large-scale asset purchase—in the hundreds of billions of dollars range—of, for example, mortgage-backed securities2 and Treasury securities. This action is commonly called “quantitative easing” (QE). …

In December 2008, the continuing severity of the crisis prompted the Fed to drop the target to the extraordinarily low range of between 0 and 0.25 percent….

[396] Webpage: “Quantitative Easing.” Bank of England. Last updated September 17, 2018. <www.bankofengland.co.uk>

Money is either physical, like banknotes, or digital, like the money in your bank account. Quantitative easing involves us creating digital money. We then use it to buy things like government debt in the form of bonds. You may also hear it called “QE” or “asset purchases”—these are the same thing.

The aim of QE is simple: by creating this “new” money, we aim to boost spending and investment in the economy.

[397] Speech: “The Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet: An Update.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 8, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Large increases in bank reserves brought about through central bank loans or purchases of securities are a characteristic feature of the unconventional policy approach known as quantitative easing. The idea behind quantitative easing is to provide banks with substantial excess liquidity in the hope that they will choose to use some part of that liquidity to make loans or buy other assets.”

[398] Working Paper: “The Macroeconomic Effects of the Federal Reserve’s Unconventional Monetary Policies.” By Eric M. Engen, Thomas Laubach, and David Reifschneider. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, January 14, 2015. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 4:

The FOMC’s [Federal Open Market Committee] QE [quantitative easing] programs were mostly comprised of large-scale asset purchases (LSAPs) of longer-term Treasury and agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS), but also included the maturity extension program (MEP)…. Cumulatively, the Federal Reserve’s holdings of Treasury notes and bonds along with agency MBS and agency debt rose from around $500 billion prior to the financial crisis to over $4 trillion when the most-recent LSAP program concluded in October 2014.

[399] Article: “The Road to Normal: New Directions in Monetary Policy.” By Stephen Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Annual Report 2015, April 8, 2016. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 10 :

Quantitative easing … involves the purchase of long-term assets (for example, 30-year Treasury bonds, which mature 30 years from the date of issue), and those assets need not be government-issued securities. …

… QE1 [the fist quantitative easing program] involved the purchase of long-term Treasury securities, agency securities and mortgage-backed securities. MBS are tradeable securities, backed by underlying private mortgages. 

[400] Article: “Quantitative Easing Explained.” By Lowell R. Ricketts. Economic Education Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, April 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 1:

QE [quantitative easing] affects the economy through changes in interest rates on long-term Treasury securities and other financial instruments (e.g., corporate bonds). To have an appreciable impact on interest rates, QE requires large-scale asset purchases. When the Fed makes such purchases of, for example, Treasury securities, the result is an increased demand for those securities, which in turn raises their prices. Treasury prices and yields (interest rates) are inversely related: As prices increase, interest rates fall. As interest rates fall, the cost to businesses for financing capital investments, such as new equipment, decreases. Over time, new business investments should bolster economic activity, create new jobs, and reduce the unemployment rate.

[401] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“[O]ur forthcoming asset-backed securities program, a joint effort with the Treasury, is not purely for liquidity provision. … If the program works as planned, it should lead to lower rates and greater availability of consumer and small business credit.”

[403] Speech: “Monetary Policy Since the Onset of the Crisis.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August 31, 2012. <www.federalreserve.gov>

In November, the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] announced a program to purchase a total of $600 billion in agency MBS [mortgage backed securities] and agency debt. In March 2009, the FOMC expanded this purchase program substantially, announcing that it would purchase up to $1.25 trillion of agency MBS, up to $200 billion of agency debt, and up to $300 billion of longer-term Treasury debt.

[404] Article: “Quantitative Easing Explained.” By Lowell R. Ricketts. Economic Education Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, April 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 1: “As interest rates fall, the cost to businesses for financing capital investments, such as new equipment, decreases. Over time, new business investments should bolster economic activity, create new jobs, and reduce the unemployment rate.”

[405] Article: “Quantitative Easing: How Well Does This Tool Work?” by Stephen D. Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, 2017. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Quantitative easing (QE)—large-scale purchases of assets by central banks—led to a large increase in the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet during the global financial crisis (2007–2008) and in the long recovery from the 2008–2009 recession. … QE consists of large-scale asset purchases by central banks, usually of long-maturity government debt but also of private assets, such as corporate debt or asset-backed securities. …

At the 2010 Jackson Hole conference, then-Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke attempted to articulate the Fed’s rationale for QE. Bernanke’s view was that, with short-term nominal interest rates at zero, purchases by the central bank of long-maturity assets would act to push up the prices of those securities because the Fed was reducing their net supply. Thus, long-maturity bond yields should go down, for example, if the Fed purchases long-maturity Treasury securities.

[406] Webpage: “What Were the Federal Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchases?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated December 22, 2015. <www.federalreserve.gov>

In conducting LSAPs [large-scale asset purchases], the Fed purchased longer-term securities issued by the U.S. government and longer-term securities issued or guaranteed by government-sponsored agencies such as Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac. … The Fed’s purchases reduced the available supply of securities in the market, leading to an increase in the prices of those securities and a reduction in their yields.

[407] “95th Annual Report, 2008.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 56:

[T]he Federal Reserve announced on November 25 a program to purchase up to $100 billion in direct obligations of housing-related government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) and up to $500 billion in MBS [mortgage-backed securities] backed by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, the Federal Home Loan Banks, and Ginnie Mae. Purchases of agency debt obligations began in December, and purchases of MBS began in January.

The program to purchase GSE direct obligations has initially focused on fixed-rate, noncallable, senior benchmark securities issued by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks.

[408] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Federal Reserve’s third set of policy tools for supporting the functioning of credit markets involves the purchase of longer-term securities for the Fed’s portfolio. For example, we recently announced plans to purchase up to $100 billion in government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) debt and up to $500 billion in GSE mortgage-backed securities over the next few quarters. Notably, mortgage rates dropped significantly on the announcement of this program and have fallen further since it went into operation. Lower mortgage rates should support the housing sector.

[409] “Chairman Bernanke’s Press Conference.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 20, 2013. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“One of the most powerful tools we have is bringing down mortgage rates and stimulating homebuying, construction, and related industries.”

[410] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

For almost a year and a half the global financial system has been under extraordinary stress—stress that has now decisively spilled over to the global economy more broadly. The proximate cause of the crisis was the turn of the housing cycle in the United States and the associated rise in delinquencies on subprime mortgages, which imposed substantial losses on many financial institutions and shook investor confidence in credit markets. …

The abrupt end of the credit boom has had widespread financial and economic ramifications. Financial institutions have seen their capital depleted by losses and writedowns and their balance sheets clogged by complex credit products and other illiquid assets of uncertain value. Rising credit risks and intense risk aversion have pushed credit spreads to unprecedented levels, and markets for securitized assets, except for mortgage securities with government guarantees, have shut down. …

… A continuing barrier to private investment in financial institutions is the large quantity of troubled, hard-to-value assets that remain on institutions’ balance sheets. The presence of these assets significantly increases uncertainty about the underlying value of these institutions and may inhibit both new private investment and new lending. …

Particularly pressing is the need to address the problem of financial institutions that are deemed “too big to fail.” It is unacceptable that large firms that the government is now compelled to support to preserve financial stability were among the greatest risk-takers during the boom period. The existence of too-big-to-fail firms also violates the presumption of a level playing field among financial institutions. In the future, financial firms of any type whose failure would pose a systemic risk must accept especially close regulatory scrutiny of their risk-taking.

[411] Webpage: “Toxic Assets.” Nasdaq. Accessed February 26, 2018 at <www.nasdaq.com>

In the context of the 2007–2009 recession, the term refers to assets like mortgage backed securities and collateralized debt obligations that are illiquid and difficult to value. If the value of the underlying assets falls significantly, these securities could lose value rapidly (aggravated by the lack of liquidity and transparency in price) which could lead to significant write-downs (and hence losses) for holders of these toxic assets.

[412] Article: “Quantitative Easing Explained.” By Lowell R. Ricketts. Economic Education Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Liber8 Economic Information Newsletter, April 2011. <files.stlouisfed.org>

Page 1: “A mortgage-backed security is an investment vehicle composed of pools of mortgages. Banks create mortgage loans that comply with standards set by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. These institutions then pool the mortgages for sale to investors. This allows banks to free up capital for other loans.”

[413] Article: “The Road to Normal: New Directions in Monetary Policy.” By Stephen Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Annual Report 2015, April 8, 2016. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Pages 8–9:

The Great Recession, dating from late 2007 to mid-2009, is generally understood as originating from severe disruption in the financial sector. … The crisis manifested itself in a collapse in the prices of U.S. real estate, which led to mortgage defaults and dysfunction in the financial markets that were closely tied to those mortgages. These markets were principally in mortgage-backed securities (MBS), which used those securities as collateral, and in derivatives. Financial distress spread through tightly connected worldwide financial markets, culminating in the failure of Lehman Brothers and the near-collapse of other large U.S. financial institutions in the latter half of 2008.

[414] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The abrupt end of the credit boom has had widespread financial and economic ramifications. Financial institutions have seen their capital depleted by losses and write-downs and their balance sheets clogged by complex credit products and other illiquid assets of uncertain value. Rising credit risks and intense risk aversion have pushed credit spreads to unprecedented levels, and markets for securitized assets, except for mortgage securities with government guarantees, have shut down. …

… A continuing barrier to private investment in financial institutions is the large quantity of troubled, hard-to-value assets that remain on institutions’ balance sheets. The presence of these assets significantly increases uncertainty about the underlying value of these institutions and may inhibit both new private investment and new lending. …

… Our economic system is critically dependent on the free flow of credit, and the consequences for the broader economy of financial instability are thus powerful and quickly felt. Indeed, the destructive effects of financial instability on jobs and growth are already evident worldwide.

[415] Paper: “Did the Federal Reserve’s MBS Purchase Program Lower Mortgage Rates?” By Diana Hancock and Wayne Passmore. Journal of Monetary Economics, July 2011. Pages 498–514. <www.sciencedirect.com>

Pages 498–499:

On Tuesday, November 25, 2008 the Federal Reserve surprised almost everyone when it announced that it would initiate a program to purchase up to $500 billion in mortgage-back securities (MBS) backed by the housing-related government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs), Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and backed by Ginnie Mae.2 The goal of this new program was to “reduce the cost and increase the availability of credit for the purchase of houses. …

The Federal Reserve’s MBS purchase program affected mortgage rates through three channels: (1) improved market functioning in both primary and secondary mortgage markets, (2) clearer government backing for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and (3) anticipation of portfolio rebalancing effects. …

… The portfolio rebalance channel works as follows: (1) when the Federal Reserve purchases an asset, it reduces the amount of the security that the private sector holds, while simultaneously increasing the amount of short-term, risk-free, bank reserves held by the private sector….

[416] Article: “Did Quantitative Easing Work?” By Edison Yu. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department Economic Insights, 2016. <www.philadelphiafed.org>

Page 9:

QE [quantitative easing] entered the market by reducing the quantity of riskier long-term assets—Treasury bonds and MBS [mortgage-backed securities]—held by private investors and increasing the amount of safer assets such as short-term Treasuries. This shift reduced the total amount of risky assets investors held, and their portfolios become safer. As a result, investors may have required less compensation to hold risky bonds and were more willing to tolerate the duration risk of long-term bonds. This effect may have lowered the risk premium on long-term bonds.

[417] “95th Annual Report, 2008.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 56–57:

In mid-March of 2008, The Bear Stearns Companies, Inc., a major investment bank and primary dealer, was pushed to the brink of failure after losing the confidence of investors and finding itself without access to short-term financing markets. A bankruptcy filing would have forced the secured creditors and counterparties of Bear Stearns to liquidate underlying collateral, and given the illiquidity of markets, those creditors and counterparties might well have sustained substantial losses. …

After discussions with the Securities and Exchange Commission and in close consultation with the Treasury, the Federal Reserve determined that it should invoke emergency authorities to provide special financing to facilitate the acquisition of Bear Stearns by JPMorgan Chase & Co. JPMorgan Chase agreed to purchase Bear Stearns and assume the company’s financial obligations. The Federal Reserve agreed to supply term funding, secured by $30 billion in Bear Stearns assets, to facilitate the purchase. …

In view of the likely systemic implications and the potential for significant adverse effects on the economy of a disorderly failure of AIG [American International Group], on September 16 [2008], the Federal Reserve Board, with the support of the Treasury, authorized the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to lend up to $85 billion to the firm to assist it in meeting its obligations and to facilitate the orderly sale of some of its businesses. …

[418] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The public in many countries is understandably concerned by the commitment of substantial government resources to aid the financial industry when other industries receive little or no assistance. This disparate treatment, unappealing as it is, appears unavoidable. …

Particularly pressing is the need to address the problem of financial institutions that are deemed “too big to fail.” It is unacceptable that large firms that the government is now compelled to support to preserve financial stability were among the greatest risk-takers during the boom period.

[419] Paper: “Federal Reserve: Unconventional Monetary Policy Options.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, February 6, 2014. <fas.org>

Page 6:

While the Fed has always lent to banks at its discount window, the amount of loans outstanding has typically been less than $1 billion throughout its history. Until 2008, it had not lent to any non-banks since the 1930s. From December 2007 to October 2008, the Fed introduced a series of emergency lending facilities for banks and non-bank financial firms and markets to restore liquidity to the financial system.8 Lending under these facilities is reported as assets on the Fed’s balance sheet. To prevent these facilities from leading to an expansion in the size of the Fed’s overall balance sheet and the money supply, the Fed sterilized (offset) the effects of the facilities on its balance sheet until September 2008 by selling a cumulative $315 billion of its Treasury securities, as seen in Figure 1.

[420] Report: “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, September 20, 2010. <www.nber.org>

“Contractions (recessions) start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. … Peak [=] December 2007 (IV) … Trough [=] June 2009 (II)”

[421] Paper: “Federal Reserve: Unconventional Monetary Policy Options.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, February 6, 2014. <fas.org>

Pages 6–7:

When the financial crisis dramatically worsened in September 2008, private liquidity became scarce, causing the Fed’s support to the financial system to increase significantly. Lending quickly exceeded the Fed’s securities holdings, making it impractical—even if it had been desired—to continue sterilizing these loans through asset sales. Instead, the Fed allowed its balance sheet to grow as lending to the financial system increased.9 Between September and November 2008, the Fed’s balance sheet more than doubled in size, increasing from less than $1 trillion to more than $2 trillion. Over the same period, support offered through liquidity facilities and for specific institutions increased from about $260 billion to $1.4 trillion.10

9 Chairman Bernanke referred to this development as “credit easing,” rather than “quantitative easing,” to distinguish it from asset purchases aimed at expanding the balance sheet. …

[422] Article: “Exiting from Monetary Stimulus: A Better Plan for the Fed.” By Benn Steil. Council on Foreign Relations, Center for Geoeconomic Studies, March 14, 2013. <cfrd8-files.cfr.org>

“In a sustained, extraordinary policy undertaking to counter the enduring economic headwinds of the 2008 financial crisis, the Fed has pumped trillions of dollars of liquidity into the banking system over the past four and a half years. It has accomplished this by buying, with newly conjured dollars, a historically unprecedented amount and variety of securities.”

[423] “95th Annual Report, 2008.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Pages 55–56:

To help reduce the cost and increase the availability of residential mortgage credit, the Federal Reserve announced on November 25 a program to purchase up to $100 billion in direct obligations of housing-related government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) and up to $500 billion in MBS [mortgage-backed securities] backed by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, the Federal Home Loan Banks, and Ginnie Mae. Purchases of agency debt obligations began in December, and purchases of MBS began in January.

The program to purchase GSE direct obligations has initially focused on fixed-rate, noncallable, senior benchmark securities issued by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks.

[424] Press Release: “FOMC Statement.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 18, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

To provide greater support to mortgage lending and housing markets, the Committee decided today to increase the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet further by purchasing up to an additional $750 billion of agency mortgage-backed securities, bringing its total purchases of these securities to up to $1.25 trillion this year, and to increase its purchases of agency debt this year by up to $100 billion to a total of up to $200 billion. Moreover, to help improve conditions in private credit markets, the Committee decided to purchase up to $300 billion of longer-term Treasury securities over the next six months.

[425] Article: “The Rise and (Eventual) Fall in the Fed’s Balance Sheet.” By Christopher J. Waller and Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, January 2014. <www.stlouisfed.org>

The first round of LSAPs [large-scale asset purchases] (QE1) began in March 2009 and ended one year later. Over the course of the program, the Fed purchased $1.25 trillion in mortgage-backed securities (MBS), $200 billion in federal agency debt (i.e., debt issued by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and Ginnie Mae to fund the purchase of mortgage loans) and $300 billion in long-term Treasury securities. The purchase of $1.45 trillion of MBS and agency debt helped to increase credit availability in private markets, revitalizing mortgage lending and propping up the beleaguered housing market. The purchase of $300 billion in long-term Treasuries was designed to put downward pressure on interest rates in general in order to bolster economic activity.

[426] Article: “The Rise and (Eventual) Fall in the Fed’s Balance Sheet.” By Christopher J. Waller and Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, January 2014. <www.stlouisfed.org>

During the summer of 2010, fears mounted that the U.S. economy could fall into a deflationary outcome similar to that experienced by Japan. … To avoid this scenario, the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] put upward pressure on inflation through a second round of LSAPs [large-scale asset purchases] (QE2). This program involved the purchase of $600 billion in long-term Treasury securities from November 2010 to June 2011 at a pace of $75 billion per month.

[427] Article: “The Rise and (Eventual) Fall in the Fed’s Balance Sheet.” By Christopher J. Waller and Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, January 2014. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Operation Twist involved the sale of short-term Treasury securities and an equal purchase of long-term Treasury securities. This put downward pressure on long-term interest rates while maintaining the same amount of securities on the Fed balance sheet. Operation Twist was started in September 2011 and was extended in June 2012 to continue through the end of 2012. In total, the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] purchased, as well as sold and redeemed, $667 billion in Treasury securities through the program, eliminating all holdings of securities with a maturity of one year or less. For comparison, about half of the portfolio fit this “one year or less” classification in July 2007, which was prior to the financial crisis.

[428] Paper: “Federal Reserve: Unconventional Monetary Policy Options.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, February 6, 2014. <fas.org>

Page 8:

On September 21, 2011, dissatisfied with slow growth and continuing weakness in the labor market, the Fed announced the Maturity Extension Program, which has been popularly coined “Operation Twist” after a similar 1961 program.16 Under this program, the Fed initially announced that it would purchase $400 billion in long-term Treasury securities and sold an equivalent amount of short-term Treasury securities from its portfolio. …[T]he Fed extended the program to the end of 2012, which resulted in the purchase and sale of an additional $267 billion of Treasury securities.17 Unlike quantitative easing, the Maturity Extension Program has no effect on the size of the Fed’s balance sheet, bank reserves, or the monetary base, and is constrained in size by the amount of short-term securities the Fed holds, and therefore can sell. It appears that the Fed chose this policy rather than another round of QE [quantitative easing] because most FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] members preferred a policy that would provide some additional stimulus, but less than an equivalent amount of QE would provide.18 By the end of 2012, the Fed’s remaining holdings of securities with a maturity of three years or less was limited, hindering its ability to use this tool again in the future.19

[429] Article: “The Rise and (Eventual) Fall in the Fed’s Balance Sheet.” By Christopher J. Waller and Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, January 2014. <www.stlouisfed.org>

To engender a stronger labor market, the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] began a third round of large-scale asset purchases (QE3) in September 2012. The purchases initially involved $40 billion in agency MBS [mortgage-backed securities] per month. However, after Operation Twist ended in December 2012, the FOMC added $45 billion in long-term Treasury securities to the monthly purchase.

[430] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 48:

Unlike its first two asset purchase programs and the MEP [Maturity Extension Program], in which the total size of the program was announced at the time the program was undertaken, the Federal Reserve’s third asset purchase program was open-ended. The FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] indicated that it would continue to purchase assets until the outlook for the labor market had improved substantially so long as inflation and expected inflation remained stable, and so long as the benefits of the purchases continued to outweigh their costs and risks.

In December 2013, the FOMC began to slow the pace of its asset purchases. It continued to slow the pace of purchases at its subsequent meetings, concluding its third asset purchase program in October 2014.

[431] Paper: “Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, January 9, 2018. <fas.org>

Page 14: “Table 1. Quantitative Easing (QE) : Changes in Asset Holdings Fed’s Balance Sheet (billions of dollars) … QE3 … Total Assets [=] + $1,663”

[432] Paper: “Federal Reserve: Unconventional Monetary Policy Options.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, February 6, 2014. <fas.org>

Pages 6–7: “Between September and November 2008, the Fed’s balance sheet more than doubled in size, increasing from less than $1 trillion to more than $2 trillion.”

[433] Paper: “Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, January 9, 2018. <fas.org>

Page 14: “Table 1. Quantitative Easing (QE) : Changes in Asset Holdings Fed’s Balance Sheet (billions of dollars) … Total (Mar. 2009–Oct. 2014) … Total Assets [=] + $2,587”

[434] Dataset: “All Federal Reserve Banks: Total Assets.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Research Division. Updated August 9, 2018. <fred.stlouisfed.org>

[435] Paper: “Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, January 9, 2018. <fas.org>

Page 14: “Table 1. Quantitative Easing (QE) : Changes in Asset Holdings Fed’s Balance Sheet (billions of dollars) … Total (Mar. 2009–Oct. 2014) … Total Assets [=] + $2,587”

[436] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 48–49:

Since the summer of 2010, the Federal Reserve has continued to reinvest the proceeds of securities that mature or prepay. Maturing Treasury securities are reinvested in Treasury securities, while principal payments on holdings of agency debt and agency MBS [mortgage-backed securities] are reinvested in agency MBS. By reinvesting, the Federal Reserve continues to hold a large amount of longer-term securities and thereby maintains downward pressure on longer-term interest rates.

[437] Article: “The Road to Normal: New Directions in Monetary Policy.” By Stephen Williamson. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Annual Report 2015, April 8, 2016. <www.stlouisfed.org>

Page 15: “[W]hen reinvestment stops, the assets on the Fed’s balance sheet will mature over time, and the balance sheet will gradually shrink in size. … Balance sheet reduction could occur through outright sales of the Fed’s assets, but there are no plans for this.”

Page 16: “How long will the balance sheet take to normalize once reinvestment stops? Studies by economists suggest that this process could take seven years or more.11 … And this is under the assumption that the Fed will not engage in more QE [quantitative easing] programs during the normalization process….”

[438] Webpage “Policy Normalization.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated June 13, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

At the June 2017 FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] meeting, all participants agreed to further augment the Committee’s Policy Normalization Principles and Plans by providing the following additional details regarding the approach the FOMC intends to use to reduce the Federal Reserve’s holdings of Treasury and agency securities once normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way.

The Committee intends to gradually reduce the Federal Reserve’s securities holdings by decreasing its reinvestment of the principal payments it receives from securities held in the System Open Market Account. Specifically, such payments will be reinvested only to the extent that they exceed gradually rising caps.

[439] Press Release: “Federal Reserve Issues FOMC Statement.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 20, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“In October, the Committee will initiate the balance sheet normalization program described in the June 2017 Addendum to the Committee’s Policy Normalization Principles and Plans.”

[440] Webpage: “What Does the Federal Reserve Mean When It Talks About the Normalization of ‘Monetary Policy’?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Last updated May 15, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The term “normalization of monetary policy” refers to plans for returning both short-term interest rates and the Federal Reserve’s securities holdings to more normal levels.

In September 2014, the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] published a statement of Policy Normalization Principles and Plans describing the overall strategy it intends to follow in normalizing the stance of monetary policy following the period of extraordinarily accommodative policies taken in the aftermath of the 2008–09 recession.

[441] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 50:

In December 2015, the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] began the normalization process by raising its target range for the federal funds rate by ¼ percentage point—the first change since December 2008—bringing the target range to 25 to 50 basis points. The FOMC based its decision on the considerable improvement in labor market conditions during 2015 and reasonable confidence that inflation, which had been running below the Committee’s objective, would rise to 2 percent over the medium term. During normalization, the FOMC is continuing to set a target range for the federal funds rate and communicate its policy through this rate.

[442] Press release: “Federal Reserve Issues FOMC Statement.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December 16, 2015. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“Given the economic outlook, and recognizing the time it takes for policy actions to affect future economic outcomes, the Committee decided to raise the target range for the federal funds rate to 1/4 to 1/2 percent.”

[443] Press release: “Federal Reserve Issues FOMC Statement.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 26, 2018. <www.federalreserve.gov>

“In view of realized and expected labor market conditions and inflation, the Committee

decided to raise the target range for the federal funds rate to 2 to 2-1/4 percent.”

[444] Paper: “Did the Federal Reserve’s MBS Purchase Program Lower Mortgage Rates?” By Diana Hancock and Wayne Passmore. Journal of Monetary Economics, July 2011. Pages 498–514. <www.sciencedirect.com>

Page 498: “On Tuesday, November 25, 2008 the Federal Reserve surprised almost everyone when it announced that it would initiate a program to purchase up to $500 billion in mortgage-backed securities (MBS) backed by the housing-related government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs), Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and backed by Ginnie Mae.”

Pages 502–503:

Mortgage market analysts generally praised the Federal Reserve MBS purchase program when it was announced. …

… [P]ress reports indicated that mortgage rates for prime borrowers (that is, borrowers of good credit quality with a 20 percent or larger down-payment) fell by as much as half of a percentage point. Indeed, this immediate and significant effect on mortgage rates likely resulted from expectations by market participants that the Federal Reserve would act to re-establish a functioning secondary mortgage market in which primary mortgage market originators would be able to finance their mortgages—at the margin—with certainty. These lower mortgage rates, in turn, set off a burst of mortgage refinancing activities by homeowners.

Page 513:

The announcement of the Federal Reserve’s MBS purchase program clearly and substantially improved market functioning and provided a strong statement of government support for U.S. mortgage markets. Moreover, the anticipation of portfolio rebalancing effects provided an important channel through which the Federal Reserve MBS purchase program substantially influenced mortgage rates.

… Our results suggest that around half of the declines in mortgage rates after the announcement of the Federal Reserve’s purchases were associated with improved market functioning and clearer government backing, and about half with portfolio rebalancing. Once the Federal Reserve’s program stabilized the mortgage market, its portfolio purchases continued to create downward pressure on mortgage rates. However, some of this downward pressure was dissipated during the first quarter of 2009, perhaps because of market confusion about the objectives of the MBS purchase program. Lastly, we find that portfolio rebalancing continued to have a substantial effect even after the program ended because of the market conditions that evolved while the Federal Reserve continued to hold a substantial portion of the stock of outstanding MBS.

[445] Speech: “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” By Ben S. Bernanke. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 13, 2009. <www.federalreserve.gov>

The Federal Reserve’s third set of policy tools for supporting the functioning of credit markets involves the purchase of longer-term securities for the Fed’s portfolio. For example, we recently announced plans to purchase up to $100 billion in government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) debt and up to $500 billion in GSE mortgage-backed securities over the next few quarters. Notably, mortgage rates dropped significantly on the announcement of this program and have fallen further since it went into operation. Lower mortgage rates should support the housing sector.

[446] Constructed with data from:

a) Dataset: “10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate, Percent, Monthly, Not Seasonally Adjusted.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Research Division. Accessed September 27, 2018 at <fred.stlouisfed.org>

b) Dataset: “Moody’s Seasoned Baa Corporate Bond Yield, Percent, Monthly, Not Seasonally Adjusted.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Research Division. Accessed September 27, 2018 at <fred.stlouisfed.org>

c) Dataset: “30-Year Fixed Rate Mortgage Average in the United States, Percent, Monthly, Not Seasonally Adjusted.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Research Division. Accessed September 27, 2018 at <fred.stlouisfed.org>

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data is available upon request.

[447] Report: “The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2013.” Congressional Budget Office, June 2016. <www.cbo.gov>

Page 1: “Market income consists of labor income, business income, capital gains (profits realized from the sale of assets), capital income excluding capital gains, income received in retirement for past services, and other sources of income.”

[448] Calculated with the dataset: “The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2013.” Congressional Budget Office, June 8, 2016. <www.cbo.gov>

“Figure 8. Cumulative Growth in Average Inflation-Adjusted Market Income, by Market Income Group, 1979 to 2013”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[449] Dataset: “The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2013.” Congressional Budget Office, June 8, 2016. <www.cbo.gov>

“Figure 8. Cumulative Growth in Average Inflation-Adjusted Market Income, by Market Income Group, 1979 to 2013”

[450] Report: “Changes in U.S. Family Finances From 2013 to 2016: Evidence From the Survey of Consumer Finances.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 12: “Median and mean inflation-adjusted net worth—the difference between families’ gross assets and their liabilities—rose between 2013 and 2016….”

[451] Report: “Changes in U.S. Family Finances From 2013 to 2016: Evidence From the Survey of Consumer Finances.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 12:

Median and mean inflation-adjusted net worth—the difference between families’ gross assets and their liabilities—rose between 2013 and 2016 (table 2). Overall, the median net worth of all families rose 16 percent to $97,300, and mean net worth rose 26 percent to $692,100. These patterns differed from the past two intervals recorded by the SCF [Survey of Consumer Finances], as there was little change in median or mean net worth in the 2010–13 period and declines in the 2007–10 period.17 These patterns in net worth over the past several surveys were largely driven by the Great Recession and subsequent recovery in house and other asset prices.

17 Between the 2013 and 2013 surveys, median net worth decreased 2 percent and mean net worth was unchanged. Between 2007 and 2010, median net worth declined 40 percent and mean net worth declined 15 percent.

[452] Calculated with the dataset: “2016 Survey of Consumer Finances, Estimates Inflation-Adjusted to 2016 Dollars, Public Data.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Table 4: “Family Net Worth, by Selected Characteristics of Families, 1989–2016 Surveys”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[453] Calculated using the dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[454] Article: “The Rise and (Eventual) Fall in the Fed’s Balance Sheet.” By Christopher J. Waller and Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, January 2014. <www.stlouisfed.org>

“Following QE2 [the second round of quantitative easing], the risks of deflation and recession subsided.”

[455] Paper: “Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, January 9, 2018. <fas.org>

Page 2: “The Fed’s unprecedentedly stimulative policy stance has been controversial. Normally, such a stance would risk resulting in higher inflation.”

[456] Article: “Did Quantitative Easing Work?” By Edison Yu. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department Economic Insights, 2016. <www.philadelphiafed.org>

Page 11:

[S]ome economists and policymakers have expressed serious concerns about the potential risk and costs associated with the program. QE [quantitative easing] is a very new policy tool, and it is difficult to know whether the unprecedented quadrupling of the Fed’s balance sheet will lead to too much liquidity and ultimately unacceptably high inflation. That is, when banks begin to lend out the reserves they have built up, the economy might grow so fast that the Fed might find it difficult to raise interest rates in time to avert runaway inflation.

[457] Calculated using the dataset: “CPI—All Urban Consumers (Current Series).” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed January 28, 2018 at <www.bls.gov>

“Series Id: CUUR0000SA0; Series Title: All Items in U.S. City Average, All Urban Consumers, Not Seasonally Adjusted; Area: U.S. City Average; Item: All Items; Base Period: 1982–84=100”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[458] Article: “The Rise and (Eventual) Fall in the Fed’s Balance Sheet.” By Christopher J. Waller and Lowell R. Ricketts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economist, January 2014. <www.stlouisfed.org>

In tandem with the expansion of the balance sheet, reserve balances held by financial institutions at the Fed have reached historic levels. … These reserves are the result of the LSAP [large-scale asset purchase] programs, whereby financial institutions were credited cash in the form of reserves in exchange for Treasury securities and MBS [mortgage-backed securities]. This process is largely why inflation pressures have been subdued during the expansion of the balance sheet. As long as these balances remain in the form of excess reserves held by the Federal Reserve, they are isolated from the real economy and contribute negligible inflation pressures. … However, as economic activity accelerates, financial institutions will have greater incentives to lend these excess reserves, and inflation pressures could manifest if reserves flow into the real economy.

[459] Paper: “Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, January 9, 2018. <fas.org>

Page 15:

The increase in the Fed’s balance sheet has the potential to be inflationary because bank reserves are a component of the portion of the money supply controlled by the fed (called the monetary base), which has grown at an unprecedented pace during QE [quantitative easing]. … The growth in the monetary base has not translated into higher inflation because bank reserves have mostly remained deposited at the Fed and have not led to increased lending or asset purchases by banks.

[460] Paper: “Federal Reserve: Unconventional Monetary Policy Options.” By Marc Labonte. Congressional Research Service, February 6, 2014. <fas.org>

Page 13: “In practice, the increase in reserves has not led to a large increase in lending or other bank activities; it appears that banks have primarily chosen to hold those reserves at the Fed. For example, total bank lending was 5% below its pre-crisis peak in nominal terms in the third quarter of 2012.”

Pages 14–15: “[E]ven if reserves have not been lent out to date, as long as they exist, they have the potential to be lent out in the future and increase the money supply, which is an important consideration for the ‘exit strategy’ from QE [quantitative easing].”

[461] Dataset: “Table 1.1.1. Percent Change From Preceding Period in Real Gross Domestic Product [Percent].” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Last revised August 29, 2018. <www.bea.gov>

“2009 [=] –2.5”

[462] Calculated using the dataset: “Table 1.1.1. Percent Change From Preceding Period in Real Gross Domestic Product [Percent].” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Last revised August 29, 2018. <www.bea.gov>

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[463] Dataset: “Table 1.1.1. Percent Change From Preceding Period in Real Gross Domestic Product [Percent].” U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Last revised August 29, 2018. <www.bea.gov>

[464] Calculated from the dataset: “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed August 8, 2018 at <data.bls.gov>

“Series Id: LNS14000000; Series Title: (Seas) Unemployment Rate, Seasonally Adjusted; Labor Force Status: Unemployment Rate; Type of Data: Percent or Rate; Age: 16 Years and Over; Years: 1948 to 2017”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[465] Calculated from the dataset: “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed August 8, 2018 at <data.bls.gov>

“Series Id: LNS14000000; Series Title: (Seas) Unemployment Rate, Seasonally Adjusted; Labor Force Status: Unemployment Rate; Type of Data: Percent or Rate; Age: 16 Years and Over; Years: 1948 to 2017”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[466] Webpage: “How the Government Measures Unemployment.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Last modified October 8, 2015. <www.bls.gov>

The employment-population ratio. This measure is the number of employed as a percentage of the civilian noninstitutional population 16 years old and over. In other words, it is the percentage of the population that is currently working.”

[467] Calculated with the dataset: “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed August 8, 2018 at <data.bls.gov>

“Series Id: LNS12300000; Series Title: (Seas) Employment-Population Ratio, Seasonally Adjusted; Labor Force Status: Employment-Population Ratio; Type of Data: Percent or Rate; Age: 16 Years and Over; Years: 2007 to 2017”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[468] Calculated with the dataset: “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed August 8, 2018 at <data.bls.gov>

“Series Id: LNS12300000; Series Title: (Seas) Employment-Population Ratio, Seasonally Adjusted; Labor Force Status: Employment-Population Ratio; Type of Data: Percent or Rate; Age: 16 Years and Over; Years: 2007 to 2017”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[469] Calculated with the dataset: “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Accessed August 8, 2018 at <data.bls.gov>

“Series Id: LNS12300000; Series Title: (Seas) Employment-Population Ratio, Seasonally Adjusted; Labor Force Status: Employment-Population Ratio; Type of Data: Percent or Rate; Age: 16 Years and Over; Years: 2007 to 2017”

NOTE: An Excel file containing the data and calculations is available upon request.

[470] Article: “Dow Finishes at All-Time High, Smashes 2007’s Record Cse.” By Jee Yeon Park. CNBC, March 5, 2013. <www.cnbc.com>

“The blue-chip index hit an all-time intraday high of 14,286.37, spiking above its previous all-time high of 14,198.10 from October 2007.”

[471] Dataset: “Dow Jones—100 Year Historical Chart.” Macrotrends. Accessed September 30, 2018 at <www.macrotrends.net>

“Date [=] 10/1/2007 … Real [=] 16813.52”

[472] Dataset: “Dow Jones—100 Year Historical Chart.” Macrotrends. Accessed September 30, 2018 at <www.macrotrends.net>

“Date [=] 2/1/2009 … Real [=] 8390.76”

[473] Report: “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, September 20, 2010. <www.nber.org>

“Contractions (recessions) start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. … Peak [=] December 2007 (IV) … Trough [=] June 2009 (II)”

[474] Book: The Federal Reserve System Purposes & Functions (10th edition). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October 2016. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Page 48: “In December 2013, the FOMC [Federal Open Market Committee] began to slow the pace of its asset purchases. It continued to slow the pace of purchases at its subsequent meetings, concluding its third asset purchase program in October 2014.”

[475] Dataset: “Dow Jones—100 Year Historical Chart.” Macrotrends. Accessed September 30, 2018 at <www.macrotrends.net>

“Date [=] 10/1/2014 … Real [=] 18468.73”

[476] Dataset: “Dow Jones—100 Year Historical Chart.” Macrotrends. Accessed September 30, 2018 at <www.macrotrends.net>

[477] Editorial: “Ronald Reagan’s Gold.” By the Editorial Board. New York Sun, February 22, 2016. <www.nysun.com>

“Headlined ‘Finish the Reagan Revolution,’ it [a campaign commercial] shows Ronald Reagan warning, as he was campaigning for president in 1980, of how the betrayal of the gold standard in the 1960s led to the inflation that was then destroying the American economy. He warned that we’d never regain price stability until we restored some form of gold backing to the dollar.”

[478] Commentary: “Jack Kemp in His Own Words.” By Jack Kemp. Wall Street Journal. Updated May 4, 2009. <www.wsj.com>

“Ronald Reagan once said he knew of no great nation in history that went off the gold standard and remained great. Since Aug. 15, 1971, when the U.S. ceased to redeem dollars held by foreign governments for gold, we have put that thesis to the test. For the first time in human history, not a single major currency in the world was linked to a commodity.”

[479] Article: “President Waits for Gold Commission Report.” By Denis G. Gulino. UPI, April 1, 1982. <www.upi.com>

“President Reagan, considered a friend of a gold standard, will wait for his advisers to sift through a negative Gold Commission report before deciding whether to link the dollar to the precious metal.”

[480] Commentary: “Volcker, Reagan and History.” By Robert J. Samuelson. Washington Post, January 11, 2015. <www.washingtonpost.com>

What Reagan provided was political protection. The Fed’s previous failures to stifle inflation reflected its unwillingness to maintain tight-money policies long enough to purge inflationary psychology. Successive presidents preferred a different approach: the wage-price policies built on the pleasing (but unrealistic) premise that these could quell inflation without jeopardizing full employment.

Reagan rejected this futile path. As the gruesome social costs of Volcker’s policies mounted—the monthly unemployment rate would ultimately rise to a post-World War II high of 10.8 percent—Reagan’s approval ratings plunged. In May 1981, they were 68 percent; by January 1983, 35 percent.

Still, he supported the Fed. “I have met with Chairman Volcker several times during the past year,” he said in early 1982. “I have confidence in the announced policies of the Federal Reserve.”

[481] Article: “The Great Inflation.” By Michael Bryan. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

In 1979, Paul Volcker, formerly the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, became chairman of the Federal Reserve Board. When he took office in August, year-over-year inflation was running above 11 percent, and national joblessness was just a shade under 6 percent. By this time, it was generally accepted that reducing inflation required greater control over the growth rate of reserves specifically, and broad money more generally. …

Over time, greater control of reserve and money growth, while less than perfect, produced a desired slowing in inflation. This tighter reserve management was augmented by the introduction of credit controls in early 1980 and with the Monetary Control Act. Over the course of 1980, interest rates spiked, fell briefly, and then spiked again. Lending activity fell, unemployment rose, and the economy entered a brief recession between January and July. Inflation fell but was still high even as the economy recovered in the second half of 1980.

But the Volcker Fed continued to press the fight against high inflation with a combination of higher interest rates and even slower reserve growth. The economy entered recession again in July 1981, and this proved to be more severe and protracted, lasting until November 1982. Unemployment peaked at nearly 11 percent, but inflation continued to move lower and by recession’s end, year-over-year inflation was back under 5 percent. In time, as the Fed’s commitment to low inflation gained credibility, unemployment retreated and the economy entered a period of sustained growth and stability. The Great Inflation was over.

[482] Article: “Recession of 1981–82.” By Tim Sablik. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, November 22, 2013. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

In late 1980 and early 1981, the Fed once again tightened the money supply, allowing the federal funds rate to approach 20 percent. …

The economy officially entered a recession in the third quarter of 1981, as high interest rates put pressure on sectors of the economy reliant on borrowing, like manufacturing and construction. … As the recession worsened, Volcker faced repeated calls from Congress to loosen monetary policy, but he maintained that failing to bring down long-run inflation expectations now would result in “more serious economic circumstances over a much longer period of time” (Monetary Policy Report 1982, 67).

Ultimately, this persistence paid off. By October 1982, inflation had fallen to 5 percent and long-run interest rates began to decline.

[483] Article: “How the Fed Seeks to Influence Interest Rates.” By Charles Davidson. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economy Matters, July 11, 2017. <www.frbatlanta.org>

It mostly comes down to one number.

That number is the federal funds rate, the interest rate financial institutions charge one another for overnight loans made from balances held at Federal Reserve banks.

But when the Fed's policy-setting Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) decides to adjust the fed funds rate, not all interest rates throughout the economy change instantaneously. Rather, monetary policy is “transmitted,” through various channels, to an array of very short-term interest rates and financial market prices. These changes, in turn, ripple through the financial system to influence rates on all kinds of loans to consumers and businesses.

Simply put, when interest rates rise, people tend to borrow less and prices tend to stabilize. When interest rates fall, people and businesses tend to borrow and spend more, which can stimulate the economy.

[484] Book: Money in Historical Perspective. By Anna J. Schwartz. University of Chicago Press, 1987. <www.nber.org>

Page 317:

The Gold Commission was established in accordance with a provision in an Act of Congress of October 7, 1980 (P.L. 96–389), of which the main matter was enlarging the quota assigned to the United States in the International Monetary Fund. The provision, introduced as an amendment to the Senate bill by Senator Jesse Helms (Republican, North Carolina), was accepted by the leadership to obtain his acquiescence to consideration by the Senate of the IMF quota enlargement. A similar arrangement was made in the House, where the amendment to the House bill was introduced by Congressman Ron Paul (Republican, Texas).

[485] “Report to the Congress of the Commission on the Role of Gold in the Domestic and International Monetary Systems: Volume I.” Gold Commission, Department of the Treasury. March 1982. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 17: “In addition, the Commission concludes that, under present circumstances, restoring a gold standard does not appear to be a fruitful method for dealing with the continuing problem of inflation.”

[486] “Report to the Congress of the Commission on the Role of Gold in the Domestic and International Monetary Systems: Volume II.” Gold Commission, Department of the Treasury. March 1982. <fraser.stlouisfed.org>

Page 269: “It is our conclusion that the temporary economic hazards of the gold standard are far less significant than those posed by a continued attempt to make the paper system work.”

[487] Book: The Case for Gold: A Minority Report of the U.S. Gold Commission. By Ron Paul and Lewis Lehrman. Cato Institute, 1982.

[488] Webpage: “Summary of House Resolution 1094: Federal Reserve Board Abolition Act.” U.S. House of Representatives, 112th Congress (2011–2012). Accessed September 20, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Paul, Ron [R-TX] (Introduced 3/15/11) …

Abolishes the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and each federal reserve bank.

Repeals the Federal Reserve Act.

[489] Article: “Ron Paul Brings His Message to University of Maryland.” By Nia-Malika Henderson. Washington Post, March 28, 2012. <www.washingtonpost.com>

The cheers went up even before Ron Paul stepped onstage to greet his adoring fans. “End the Fed! End the Fed! End the Fed!” they shouted, stomping their feet and yelling about a coming revolution.

In the run-up to Tuesday’s presidential primaries in Maryland and the District, Paul—down in the Republican delegate race but a cult hero among many—brought his bold and folksy message to a packed auditorium at the University of Maryland.

[490] Book: End the Fed. By Ron Paul. Grand Central Publishing, September 16, 2009.

[491] Article: “Jack Kemp, Star on Field and in Politics, Dies at 73.” By Adam Clymer. New York Times, May 2, 2009. <www.nytimes.com>

“Mr. Kemp was secretary of housing and urban development under the first President George Bush and the Republican vice-presidential nominee in 1996. But his greatest legacy may stem from his years as a congressman from Buffalo, especially 1978, when his argument for sharp tax cuts to promote economic growth became party policy, one that has endured to this day.”

[492] Commentary: “In His Own Words: Jack Kemp and the Issues.” By Jack Kemp. New York Times, August 11, 1996. <www.nytimes.com>

From a position paper for Empower America:

“The new President should instruct the Treasury secretary to stabilize the dollar value of the nation’s gold reserves, say within a $30 band, as a critical first step toward restoring sound money to America. This action would reinstate the dollar/gold link that was broken in 1971, which led to the most severe run of inflation in our nation’s history. … It has long been my belief that it will never be possible to balance the Federal budget without some kind of dollar/gold link.”

[493] Webpage: “Summary of House Resolution 5986: Gold Standard Act of 1984.” U.S. House of Representatives, 98th Congress (1983–1984). Accessed March 1, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Kemp, Jack [R-NY] (Introduced 06/29/84) …

Requires the Secretary of the Treasury, by one year after enactment of this Act, to establish a permanent definition of the dollar, expressed as a fixed weight of gold, nine-tenths fine.

Declares that the dollar so defined shall be the standard and unit of value of the United States.

Permits any person, after such time, to redeem for gold at any Federal Reserve bank any currency or coin of the United States or any demand note or demand liability of a Federal Reserve bank.

Requires the Secretary to mint gold coins in such weights, denominations, and forms as will best serve the maintenance of gold payments and the needs of commerce.

Makes such gold coins legal tender for all debts, public charges, taxes, and dues.

Permits the exchange of gold bullion for gold coins which contain an equal weight of fine gold minus a charge which shall not exceed mint costs and related expenses.

Requires the Secretary and the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System to prescribe rules and regulations to carry out this Act.

Repeals restrictions on gold payments and gold ownership.

[494] Article: “Clinton Nominates Greenspan to New Term.” By Paul Richter and Jonathan Peterson. Los Angeles Times, February 23, 1996. <articles.latimes.com>

“Voting for continuity in monetary policy, President Clinton on Thursday nominated Alan Greenspan to a third term as chairman of the Federal Reserve Board.”

[495] Article: “Clinton Asks Greenspan to Stick Around.” By Beth Piskora. New York Post, January 5, 2000. <nypost.com>

“Clinton gave credit where credit is due yesterday when he officially nominated Greenspan, 73, to a fourth term at the Fed, a long expected move.”

[496] Article: “A Brief History of the Federal Reserve’s Independence.” By Nick Timiraos. Wall Street Journal, June 13, 2017. <www.wsj.com>

‘It was clear to me … having an independent Fed in terms of its decisions and credibility was critically important,’ said former Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin, who in 1993 established a rule within the Clinton White House that the Fed’s policy decisions shouldn’t be publicly questioned.”

[497] Speech: “Remarks on the Renomination of Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan and an Exchange with Reporters.” By William J. Clinton. American Presidency Project, January 4, 2000. <www.presidency.ucsb.edu>

Since I took office 7 years ago, one of the hallmarks of our economic strategy has been a respect for the independence and the integrity of the Federal Reserve. I have always believed the best way for the executive branch to work with the Fed is to let the Chairman and the members do their jobs independently, while we do our job to promote fiscal discipline, to open markets, to invest in people and technologies. That has given us strong economic growth with low inflation and low unemployment.

[498] Article: “Riegle–Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994.” By Bill Medley. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Federal Reserve History, September 1994. <www.federalreservehistory.org>

The Riegle–Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994 removed many of the restrictions on opening bank branches across state lines. … In addition, the act allowed banking organizations to acquire banks in any other state under a uniform, nationwide standard. …

As passed, the Riegle–Neal Interstate Banking Act of 1994 provided for uniform branching and interstate acquisition rules for the entire country. …

Following the Senate’s passage of the Act on September 13, 1994, President Bill Clinton praised the new legislation. “Today this country took an historic step, one that had been delayed for much too long, to help American banks better meet the needs of our people, our communities and our economy,” Clinton said (Clinton 1994).

[499] Article: “Forbes the Candidate: Different Hat, Same Message.” By Dierdre Carmody. New York Times, December 4, 1995. <www.nytimes.com>

“When Malcolm S. Forbes Jr., the chief executive of Forbes Inc. and the editor in chief of Forbes magazine, announced on Sept. 22 that he would seek the Republican nomination for President, relatively few people had heard of the self-effacing and somewhat shy 48-year-old candidate.”

[500] Article: “Forbes Declares Candidacy on Internet and the Stump.” By Richard L. Berke. New York Times, March 17, 1999. <www.nytimes.com>

“Renouncing the traditional brass bands and patriotic bunting, Steve Forbes, the multimillionaire publisher, today became the first Presidential contender to formally announce his candidacy on the Internet.”

[501] Article: “Forbes’s Silver Bullet for the Nation’s Malaise.” By Elizabeth Kohlbert. New York Times, January 1, 1996. <www.nytimes.com>

Along with the flat tax, Mr. Forbes calls for a return to something like the gold standard, which would tie the value of the dollar to a fixed measure. Aides say he does not actually advocate bringing back the gold standard—something almost no economist would support—but is simply advocating a policy similar to the anti-inflationary program the Federal Reserve has in recent years pursued. Nevertheless, Mr. Forbes maintains that his policy, unlike the Federal Reserve’s, would bring mortgage rates down to 4.5 percent.

[502] Commentary: “Why Stocks Are Wobbly.” By Steve Forbes. Forbes, February 6, 2018. <www.forbes.com>

The dollar. Markets are finally waking up to the implications of the weak dollar, which has been declining for months. The greenback’s slide has been nowhere as bad as it was in the early 2000s, but the trend isn’t good. Treasury secretary Steven Mnuchin let the cat out of the bag a few days ago when he called for a dollar devaluation. As he soon learned, this is a no-no. You aren’t supposed to be so open and blunt. His predecessors could have coached him on how to signal you want a cheaper dollar without explicitly saying so. Chastened, Mnuchin claimed he was misquoted. But the markets got the message all too clearly: We’re in for a repeat of letting the dollar fall in value that was the disastrous hallmark of George Bush’s treasury secretaries.

An unstable and weak dollar does to marketplace prices what a virus does to a computer: It corrupts information. Prices are supposed to tell us the value of a product or service. If the price is going up, it signals that people want more of the thing. If it’s moving down, that means either people don’t want it as much or the supplier, through productivity, has made it more affordable. Prices in free markets are supersensitive, real-time conveyors of consumer wants and dislikes. They give us priceless information without which the economy couldn’t function.

[503] Book: Money: How the Destruction of the Dollar Threatens the Global Economy—and What We Can Do About It. By Steve Forbes and Elizabeth Ames. McGraw-Hill Education, June 3, 2014.

[504] Press Release: “Schumer Statement on Tenure of Janet Yellen and Nomination of Jerome Powell for Federal Reserve Chair.” Senate Democrats, November 2, 2017. <www.democrats.senate.gov>

“Chair Yellen helped steer our economy with precision, transparency, and remarkable intellect, so it’s hard to understand why the administration would elect to make her the first fed chair in decades to not be re-nominated for a second term. In my view, her sure hand, and the steady growth and low inflation over her tenure, certainly warranted a reappointment.”

[505] Article: “Schumer Says Obama Should Nominate Yellen as Fed Chair.” By David Lawder. Reuters, September 18, 2013. <www.reuters.com>

Speaking at a news conference, Schumer, a New York Democrat who serves on the Senate Banking Committee, said that he had previously supported either Yellen or former White House adviser Lawrence Summers to succeed Ben Bernanke as the head of the U.S. central bank next year.

Now that Summers has dropped out, “I think the president should choose Yellen,” he said.

[506] Article: “Nominee for Fed Chief Wins Backing of Schumer.” By Edmund Andrews. New York Times, November 11, 2005. <www.nytimes.com>

A leading Senate Democrat on Thursday endorsed President Bush’s nomination of Ben S. Bernanke to become chairman of the Federal Reserve.

“I think he’s going to be an outstanding Fed chairman, and I think he’s going to be in the mold of Alan Greenspan,” said Senator Charles E. Schumer of New York, a member of the Senate Banking Committee, after a 45-minute meeting with Mr. Bernanke.

[507] Article: “Senators Slam Bernanke, Then Confirm Him to Second Term.” By David Lightman and Kevin G. Hall. McClatchy, January 28, 2010. <www.mcclatchydc.com>

Sen. Charles Schumer, D-N.Y., said that Bernanke’s creative steps—such as broadening the universe of institutions that could receive Fed support and lending directly to big corporations that needed to roll over short-term debt—brought the economy back from the edge of an abyss.

“Nobody was more important in preventing the collapse … than Chairman Bernanke. I was there in the meetings, and I saw his steady hand,” Schumer said.

[508] Article: “Here’s What Sen. Charles Schumer Wants to Tell Janet Yellen on Tuesday.” By Robert Schroeder. MarketWatch, July 14, 2014. <blogs.marketwatch.com>

Schumer said he believes the “overwhelming problem” still faced by the economy is the lack of job growth.

“So I am going to encourage [the Fed] to be careful before they move to raise rates,” due to the impact that could have on job growth, Schumer said.

[509] Webpage: “Roll Call Vote 114th Congress—2nd Session.” U.S. Senate, January 12, 2016. <www.senate.gov>

Vote Summary

Question: On Cloture on the Motion to Proceed (Motion to Invoke Cloture on the Motion to Proceed to S. 2232) …

Vote Date: January 12, 2016, 02:31 PM …

Measure Number: S. 2232 (Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2015)

Measure Title: A bill to require a full audit of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Federal reserve banks by the Comptroller General of the United States, and for other purposes. …

Schumer (D-NY), Nay

[510] Article: “Could President Gingrich Fire Fed Chair Bernanke?” By Eric Black. MinnPost, November 18, 2011. <www.minnpost.com>

Among the promises Gingrich routinely makes of things he would do as president, promises to fire Federal Reserve Board Chair Ben Bernanke, to whom Gingrich assigns substantial blame for the economic meltdown and the failure of the economy to bounce back more strongly. He likes the term “disastrous” to describe Bernanke’s performance and says that Bernanke is the “first person” who needs to be fired.

[511] “Statement by Newt Gingrich on Federal Reserve Announcement.” By Newt Gingrich. American Presidency Project, September 21, 2011. <www.presidency.ucsb.edu>

Newt Gingrich released the following statement reacting to the Federal Reserve’s bond purchasing and selling announcement:

“The Federal Reserve should not be making economic policy. As President, I will send to Congress legislation that returns the institution to its proper, limited role of stabilizing prices and preventing rampant inflation.”

[512] Article: “Gingrich Steps on Ron Paul’s Turf with Push for Federal Reserve Audit.” By Michael O’Brien. The Hill, June 22, 2011. <thehill.com>

“Former House Speaker Newt Gingrich (R-Ga.) is looking to stake out some of Rep. Ron Paul’s (R-Texas) political turf with his push this week for an audit of the Federal Reserve.”

[513] Article: “Gingrich: U.S. Should Reconsider Gold Standard.” By Chris Isidore. CNN Money, January 18, 2012. <money.cnn.com>

“Republican presidential candidate Newt Gingrich is calling for the United States to think about returning to the gold standard. Speaking at a foreign policy forum in South Carolina on Tuesday, Gingrich advocated a ‘commission on gold to look at the whole concept of how do we get back to hard money.’ … Gingrich would model his ‘gold commission’ after one put in place after Ronald Reagan was elected….”

[514] Commentary: “The Greatest Threat to the Trump Recovery Is Reckless Action by the Federal Reserve.” By Newt Gingrich. Fox News, February 6, 2018. <www.foxnews.com>

Now, as the economy recovers, the Fed is reverting to its normal fear of prosperity.

Back in the 1970s and 1980s, then-Congressman Jack Kemp and I argued that the attitude of the Federal Reserve was both wrong intellectually and wrong in practical effect.

The dominant Fed theory is that too much economic growth is dangerous because it leads to inflation. Therefore, every time the economy starts growing substantially, the Fed should raise interest rates to “cool it off.”

Since many Fed economists agree with former Treasury Secretary Larry Summers that stagnant growth is the “new normal,” they believe it is essential that interest rates be raised every time the economy starts to really grow.

[515] Article: “Obama to Reappoint Bernanke as Fed Chief.” By Jon Hilsenrath, David Wessel, and Sudeep Reddy. Wall Street Journal. Updated August 25, 2009. <www.wsj.com>

President Barack Obama will announce the nomination of Ben Bernanke to a second term as Federal Reserve chairman on Tuesday, opting for continuity in U.S. economic policy despite criticism in Congress of the low-key central banker’s frantic efforts to rescue the financial system.

Wall Street and academic economists in recent weeks showed enthusiasm for giving Mr. Bernanke a second term, and some administration insiders felt similarly even though Mr. Bernanke was appointed by—and served in the White House of—President George W. Bush.

[516] Article: “Announcing Fed Nomination, Obama Praises Yellen.” By Jackie Calmes. New York Times, October 10, 2013. <www.nytimes.com>

President Obama on Wednesday announced what he called perhaps his most important economic decision, nominating Janet L. Yellen to lead the Federal Reserve system and be his independent co-steward of the economy, calling her “one of the nation’s foremost economists and policy makers.” …

For the announcement, she joined Mr. Obama in the State Dining Room of the White House, along with the retiring chairman, Ben S. Bernanke, whom the president hailed for helping guide the economy through the worst financial crisis since the Depression.

[517] Article: “Obama Defends QE2 Ahead of G20.” By Graeme Wearden. The Guardian, November 8, 2010. <www.theguardian.com>

With many commentators predicting heated discussions between world leaders when they meet in Seoul later this week, Obama hit back at claims that the Federal Reserve risked destabilizing the world economy through the $600bn (£370bn) “QE2” programme announced last week. During a visit to India, Obama argued that stimulating the US economy was in everyone’s interests.

“I will say that the Fed’s mandate, my mandate, is to grow our economy. And that’s not just good for the United States, that’s good for the world as a whole,” said Obama, during a press conference in New Delhi. “And the worst thing that could happen to the world economy, not just ours, is if we end up being stuck with no growth or very limited growth,” he added.

[518] Article: “Senate Democrats Come Out Against Fed Audit Bill.” By Michael Flaherty. Reuters, February 11, 2015. <www.reuters.com>

“President Barack Obama would likely veto a Fed audit but there is also a chance it could be added as an amendment to ‘must-pass’ legislation, such as with the bill to fund the Department of Homeland Security.”

[519] Article: “WH Official: ‘Audit the Fed’ Bill Is ‘Dangerous.’ ” By Peter Schroeder. The Hill, February 10, 2015. <thehill.com>

One of President Obama’s top economic advisers said Tuesday he opposed “dangerous” legislation that would give lawmakers closer scrutiny over Federal Reserve deliberations.

Jason Furman, chairman of Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers, called pending legislation subjecting monetary policy deliberations to outside review “somewhere between superfluous and highly counterproductive.”

He added that he would encourage President Obama to oppose the bill if it reached his desk. That opposition could be noteworthy, as previous efforts have stalled in a Democrat-led Senate, which is now in GOP control.

[520] Webpage: “Summary of House Resolution 6053: Price Stability Act of 2008.” U.S. House of Representatives, 110th Congress (2007–2008). Accessed March 4, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Ryan, Paul [R-WI] (Introduced 5/14/2008) …

Declares it is US policy that the principal economic responsibilities of the Government are to establish both long-term economic growth and increases in living standards, maintain free markets, low taxes, respect for private property, and the stable, long-term purchasing power of US currency.

Declares that the promotion of price stability should be the primary long-term goal of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Amends the Federal Reserve Act to revise the mandate of the Board and the Federal Open Market Committee to require them to: (1) establish a numerical definition of the term “price stability”; and (2) maintain a monetary policy that promotes long-term price stability.

Requires the Board to consult with, and report to, Congress semi-annually about Board and Committee objectives and plans to achieve and maintain price stability.

Repeals the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.

[521] Commentary: “A Republican Road to Economic Recovery.” By Paul Ryan. Wall Street Journal. Updated March 2, 2009. <www.wsj.com>

“I believe the best way to guarantee sound money is to use an explicit, market-based price guide, such as a basket of commodities, in setting monetary policy. A more politically realistic path to price stability would be for the Fed to explicitly embrace inflation targeting.”

[522] Press release: “Pelosi Statement on the Nomination of Dr. Janet Yellen as the First Woman to Chair the Federal Reserve.” Democratic Leader, October 9, 2013. <www.democraticleader.gov>

President Obama’s decision to nominate Dr. Janet Yellen to head the Federal Reserve marks yet another historic step for women, for our economy, and for our country. With her exceptional economic expertise, her extensive experience inside the Federal Reserve, and her unwavering dedication to fighting inflation, reducing unemployment, and promoting America’s economic growth, Dr. Yellen has more than earned her seat at the head of the table.

[523] Press release: “Pelosi Statement on the Nomination of Jerome Powell for Federal Reserve Chairman.” Democratic Leader, November 2, 2017 <www.democraticleader.gov>

Outgoing Chairwoman Janet Yellen leaves an exceptional legacy for women, our economy and our country. Dr. Yellen’s brilliant mind and firm leadership have been transformative for our nation, and her steady hand on the tiller turned a struggling economy into an engine of strong and steady growth. Her progress in reducing unemployment, growing wages and promoting more equal growth will long benefit the American people.

As Federal Reserve Chairman, Jerome Powell will have the immense responsibility of keeping the economy and markets stable and growing during a time of constant Republican attacks on middle class families. Democrats are hopeful that Powell will uphold and strengthen the Dodd–Frank Act’s historic consumer protections that safeguard the American people against reckless and abusive practices by unscrupulous players on Wall Street. We also expect him to exercise the central bank’s powers judiciously and wisely to reduce inequality and promote broad-based economic prosperity for all American families.

[524] “Transcript of Pelosi Press Conference Today.” Democratic Leader, July 26, 2012. <www.democraticleader.gov>

Q: The vote on the Fed, audit the Fed bill this week was roughly bipartisan.

Leader Pelosi: This big vote.

Q: And the Fed is making a decision in the coming meeting or two about whether or not to try to do more quantitative easing, and now they have this political thing to think about. Was it irresponsible of Members to sort of fire warning shots essentially at the Federal Reserve on this issue?

Leader Pelosi: I’m not going to say it is irresponsible, it’s just that. Just a shot. It’s probably not going to be the law. But the fact is that that bill covered more territory than I think it should have. I did not vote for it. There is interest in monitoring the Fed from the standpoint of certain of its activities. But if Congress gets in the business of monitoring the Fed in terms of monetary policy, I think it is a very—I don’t think that’s a very good path to go down. And I don’t know that everyone who voted for the bill was subscribing to that part of the bill.

[525] Commentary: “Sen. Rand Paul: The Fed Is Crippling America.” By Sen. Rand Paul and Mark Spitznagel. Time, January 10, 2016. <time.com>

On Jan. 12, Congress is scheduled to vote on the ‘Audit the Fed’ legislation (H.R. 24/S. 264), which, if passed, would bring to an end to the Federal Reserve’s unchecked—and even arguably unconstitutional—power in the financial markets and the economy. …

The Fed is, indeed, a political, oligarchic force, and a key part of what looks and functions like a banking cartel. During the 2007–08 financial crisis, the Fed’s true nature was clear to anyone paying attention. As the Treasury began bailing out the investment banks … the Fed moved in tandem, further purchasing the underwater assets of these institutions, as well as actually paying interest to the commercial banks (hemorrhaging from risky loans) for reserves they kept parked at the Fed. …

[526] Webpage: “Summary of Senate Bill S.202: Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2011.” U.S. Senate, 112th Congress (2011–2012). Accessed September 20, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Paul, Rand [R–KY] (Introduced 1/26/11)

Directs the Comptroller General to complete, before the end of 2012, an audit of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and of the federal reserve banks, followed by a detailed report to Congress.

Repeals specified limitations on such an audit.

[527] Webpage: “Summary of Senate Bill S.209: Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2013.” U.S. Senate, 113th Congress (2013–2014). Accessed September 20, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Paul, Rand [R–KY] (Introduced 2/4/13)

Directs the Comptroller General (GAO) to: (1) complete, within 12 months of enactment of this Act, the required audit of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Board) and of the Federal Reserve Banks; and (2) submit to Congress, within 90 days of audit completion, a detailed report of audit findings and conclusions.

Repeals certain limitations placed upon such audit.

Instructs the Comptroller General (GAO) to audit and report on the review of loan files of homeowners in foreclosure in 2009 or 2010, required as part of the enforcement actions taken by the Board against supervised financial institutions. Prescribes audit contents, including: (1) the guidance given by the Board to independent consultants retained by the supervised financial institutions regarding procedures to be followed in conducting the file reviews, (2) the factors considered by independent consultants when evaluating loan files and the results obtained pursuant to those reviews, and (3) the determinations made by such consultants regarding the nature and extent of financial injury sustained by each homeowner as well as the level and type of remediation offered.

[528] Webpage: “Summary of Senate Bill S.264: Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2015.” U.S. Senate, 114th Congress (2015–2016). Accessed September 20, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Paul, Rand [R–KY] (Introduced 1/27/15)

This bill directs the Government Accountability Office (GAO) to: (1) commence and complete an audit of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and of the Federal Reserve Banks within 12 months of enactment of this Act, and (2) report findings and conclusions to Congress within 90 days of completing the audit.

The bill also repeals certain limitations upon such an audit.

GAO shall audit and report on the review of loan files of homeowners in foreclosure in 2009 or 2010, required as part of the enforcement actions taken by the Board against supervised financial institutions.

Audit contents shall include: (1) the guidance given by the Board to independent consultants retained by the supervised financial institutions regarding procedures to be followed in conducting the file reviews; (2) the factors considered by independent consultants when evaluating loan files and the results obtained pursuant to those reviews; and (3) the determinations made by such consultants regarding the nature and extent of financial injury sustained by each homeowner, as well as the level and type of remediation offered.

[529] Webpage: “Summary of Senate Bill S.16: Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2017.” U.S. Senate, 115th Congress (2017–2018). Accessed March 1, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Paul, Rand [R–KY] (Introduced 1/3/17)

This bill directs the Government Accountability Office (GAO) to complete, within 12 months, an audit of the Federal Reserve Board and Federal Reserve banks.

In addition, the bill allows the GAO to audit the Federal Reserve Board and Federal Reserve banks with respect to: (1) international financial transactions; (2) deliberations, decisions, or actions on monetary policy matters; (3) transactions made under the direction of the Federal Open Market Committee; and (4) discussions or communications among Federal Reserve officers, board members, and employees regarding any of these matters.

[530] Commentary: “To Rein In Wall Street, Fix the Fed.” By Bernie Sanders. New York Times, December 23, 2015. <www.nytimes.com>

… The chief executives of some of the largest banks in America are allowed to serve on its boards. …

If I were elected president, the foxes would no longer guard the henhouse. To ensure the safety and soundness of our banking system, we need to fundamentally restructure the Fed’s governance system to eliminate conflicts of interest. … Banking industry executives must no longer be allowed to serve on the Fed’s boards and to handpick its members and staff. Board positions should instead include representatives from all walks of life—including labor, consumers, homeowners, urban residents, farmers and small businesses.

We also need transparency. Too much of the Fed’s business is conducted in secret, known only to the bankers on its various boards and committees. …

… We need to go further and require the Government Accountability Office to conduct a full and independent audit of the Fed each and every year.

[531] Commentary: “To Rein In Wall Street, Fix the Fed.” By Bernie Sanders. New York Times, December 23, 2015. <www.nytimes.com>

The recent decision by the Fed to raise interest rates is the latest example of the rigged economic system. … As a rule, the Fed should not raise interest rates until unemployment is lower than 4 percent. Raising rates must be done only as a last resort—not to fight phantom inflation. …

The Fed must also make sure that financial institutions are investing in the productive economy by providing affordable loans to small businesses and consumers that create good jobs. … [T]he Fed must stop providing incentives for banks to keep money out of the economy. Since 2008, the Fed has been paying financial institutions interest on excess reserves parked at the central bank—reserves that have grown to an unprecedented $2.4 trillion. That is insane. Instead of paying banks interest on these reserves, the Fed should charge them a fee that would be used to provide direct loans to small businesses.

[534] Article: “Ted Cruz Calls for the Gold Standard.” By Reem Nasr. CNBC, October 28, 2015. <www.cnbc.com>

‘I think the Fed should get out of the business of trying to juice our economy, and simply be focused on sound money and monetary stability, ideally tied to gold,’ he [Cruz] said during the Republican presidential debate.”

[535] Article: “Cruz Steps Outside GOP Orthodoxy with Free-Market Criticism of Fed.” By Joseph Lawler. Washington Examiner, December 4, 2015. <www.washingtonexaminer.com>

The conservative Texas senator and contender for the GOP presidential nomination argues that the central bank is responsible for causing the financial crisis and recession because it kept money too tight in 2008.

The Texan aired his views Thursday in a direct confrontation with Yellen during her testimony before the Joint Economic Committee.

Cruz began a round of questioning by stating that, in the summer of 2008, “the Federal Reserve told markets that it was shifting to a tighter monetary policy. This, in turn, set off a scramble for cash, which caused the dollar to soar, asset prices to collapse and [the consumer price index] to fall below zero, which set the stage for the financial crisis.”

[536] Webpage: “Summary of House Resolution 2912: Centennial Monetary Commission Act of 2015.” U.S. House of Representatives, 114th Congress (2015–2016). Accessed March 4, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Brady, Kevin [R-TX] (Introduced 6/25/15) …

This bill establishes the Centennial Monetary Commission to: (1) examine how U.S. monetary policy since the creation of the Federal Reserve Board in 1913 has affected the performance of the U.S. economy in terms of output, employment, prices, and financial stability over time; (2) evaluate various operational regimes under which the Board and the Federal Open Market Committee may conduct monetary policy in terms achieving the maximum sustainable level of output and employment and price stability over the long term; (3) evaluate the use of macro-prudential supervision and regulation and of the lender-of-last-resort function of the Board as tools of monetary policy in terms of achieving the maximum sustainable level of output and employment and price stability over the long term; and (4) recommend a course for U.S. monetary policy going forward.

[537] Webpage: “Summary of House Resolution 4180: Sound Dollar Act of 2012.” U.S. House of Representatives, 112th Congress (2011–2012). Accessed March 4, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Brady, Kevin [R-TX] (Introduced 3/8/12) …

Amends the Federal Reserve Act (FRA) to direct the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Board) and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) to: (1) promote the goal of long-term price stability, and (2) establish metrics to evaluate whether long-term price stability is being achieved.

[538] Webpage: “Summary of House Resolution 3189: Fed Oversight Reform and Modernization Act of 2015.” U.S. House of Representatives, 114th Congress (2015–2016). Accessed March 4, 2018 at <www.congress.gov>

Sponsor: Huizenga, Bill [R-MI] (Introduced 7/23/15) …

This bill amends the Federal Reserve Act to require the Chairman of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), within 48 hours after the end of a FOMC meeting, to submit to the appropriate congressional committees and the Government Accountability Office (GAO) a Directive Policy Rule, meeting specified criteria, accompanied by a statement identifying the FOMC members voting in its favor.

A Directive Policy Rule shall describe the FOMC strategy or rule for the systematic quantitative adjustment of a Policy Instrument Target to:

• respond to a change in specified Intermediate Policy Inputs, and

• provide the basis for an Open Market Operations Directive to achieve a specified Policy Instrument Target presented by the FOMC to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to guide open-market operations.

The GAO shall determine if a Directive Policy Rule has materially changed from the rule most recently submitted, and the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Board) must testify within seven legislative days before certain congressional committees as to why any noncompliance exists.

[539] Article: “With Trump in Power, the Fed Gets Ready for a Reckoning.” By Binyamin Appelbaum. New York Times, November 12, 2016. <www.nytimes.com>

“In early September, he [Trump] said the Fed was supporting a ‘very false economy’ by driving asset prices to what he described as unsustainable heights. ‘We are in a big, fat, ugly bubble,’ Mr. Trump said during the first presidential debate, a few weeks later.”

[540] “Interview with the Candidate: Donald Trump (Web Extra).” By Josh McElveen. WMUR, updated March 27, 2015. <www.wmur.com>

Question: Can you envision a scenario that this country ever goes back to a gold standard?

Trump: In some ways, I like the gold standard and there are some very nice things about it. You have to go back at the right time, when gold does the el crasho. But there is something very nice about having something solid. We used to have a very solid country because it was based on a gold standard. We do not have that anymore. There is something very nice about the concept of that. It would be very hard to do at this point and one of the problems is, we do not have the gold. Other places have the gold.

[541] Article: “Mr. Ordinary: Who Is Jerome Powell, Trump’s Federal Reserve Pick?” By Nick Timiraos and David Harrison. Wall Street Journal, November 2, 2017. <www.wsj.com>

Mr. Powell, judging by his nearly 40-year career in government, law and banking, is likely to be in the latter group [of consensus builders]. That means a Powell Fed might look a lot like it has since Mr. Greenspan retired in 2006.

Such continuity would be welcome in the markets, which don’t like uncertainty, and at the Fed, one of the world’s most powerful economic policy-making bodies. It also could please Mr. Trump, who has spoken approvingly of record stock prices and declining unemployment.

His appointment could also cause friction within the Republican Party, where many rank-and-file members want to see the Fed roll back a decade of central-bank activism sparked by the financial crisis.

[542] Press Release: “Statement by Federal Reserve Board Governor Powell on His Nomination by President Trump.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, November 2, 2017. <www.federalreserve.gov>

Finally, I have had the great privilege of serving under Chairman Bernanke and Chair Yellen, who guided the economy with insight and courage through difficult times while moving monetary policy toward greater transparency and predictability. Each of them embodies the highest ideals of public service—unquestioned integrity and unflinching commitment to fulfilling our mandate. Inside the Federal Reserve, we understand that monetary policy decisions matter for American families and communities. I strongly share that sense of mission and am committed to making decisions with objectivity and based on the best available evidence, in the longstanding tradition of monetary policy independence.

[543] Article: “Trump and Dollar: Friend or Foe?” By Trevor Hunnicutt and Saqib Iqbal Ahmed. Reuters, July 19, 2018. <www.reuters.com>

In January 2017, after a post-election run-up in the dollar, Trump said the currency was “too strong.” In April 2017 he reiterated that stance. But that July Trump said he liked a dollar that was “not too strong.” …

The U.S. trade deficit and the loss of manufacturing jobs that Trump blames on unfair advantages enjoyed by other countries have been centerpieces of his economic policies. A strong dollar makes exports more expensive to purchasers. “A strong dollar would undermine his stance on trade,” said Eric Stein, co-director of global income group at Eaton Vance Management. “We might hear more beating of the drum about a weaker dollar.”

[544] Article: “Trump Says ‘Strong Dollar’ May Be Too Strong for Its Own Good.” MarketWatch, April 13, 2017. <www.marketwatch.com>

“Look, there’s some very good things about a strong dollar, but usually speaking the best thing about it is that it sounds good.” – President Donald Trump

That’s the second, and less attention-grabbing (but arguably more revealing), sentence of an answer President Trump gave to a question about the U.S. dollar’s relative strength during a White House interview Wednesday with Wall Street Journal reporters.

The previous sentence of his response found him accepting “blame” for the dollar’s elevated level on the currency market. (“I think our dollar is getting too strong, and partially that’s my fault because people have confidence in me.”)

Just Facts | 641 Shunpike Rd #286 | Chatham, NJ 07928 | Contact Us

Copyright © Just Facts. All rights reserved.
Just Facts is a nonprofit 501(c)3 organization.
Information provided by Just Facts is not legal, tax, or investment advice.
justfacts.com | justfactsdaily.com